Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Consider the common-value auction described in this chapter, where \(Y=y_{1}+y_{2}\) and \(y_{1}\) and \(y_{2}\) are both uniformly distributed on \([0,10]\). Player \(i\) privately observes \(y_{i}\). Players simultaneously submit bids and the one who bids higher wins. (a) Suppose player 2 uses the bidding strategy \(b_{2}\left(y_{2}\right)=3+y_{2}\). What is player 1's best-response bidding strategy? (b) Suppose each player will not select a strategy that would surely give him/her a negative payoff conditional on winning the auction. Suppose also that this fact is common knowledge between the players. What can you conclude about how high the players are willing to bid? (c) Show that for every fixed number \(z>0\), there is no Bayesian Nash equilibrium in which the players both use the bidding strategy \(b_{i}=y_{i}+z\).

Short Answer

Expert verified
(a) Player 1's best-response is \(b_1(y_1) = y_1 + 2\). (b) Bids cannot exceed \(y_i + 5\). (c) No equilibrium exists for strategies \(b_i = y_i + z\) with \(z > 0\).

Step by step solution

01

Calculating Expected Value

For player 1, who observes their own signal \(y_1\) and knows the auction format \(Y = y_1 + y_2\), we need to consider the expected value of \(Y\) given the observed \(y_1\). The expected value of \(y_2\) given a uniform distribution from 0 to 10 is 5. Therefore, the expected value of \(Y\) given \(y_1\) is \(E[Y|y_1] = y_1 + 5\).
02

Determining Payoff

Player 1's payoff when winning is \(E[Y|y_1] - b_1(y_1)\), where \(b_1(y_1)\) is player 1's bid. To ensure non-negative payoff from winning, player 1 requires \(b_1(y_1) \leq E[Y|y_1] = y_1 + 5\).
03

Finding Best-Response Strategy for Player 1

Given player 2's strategy is \(b_2(y_2) = 3 + y_2\), player 1 wins if \(b_1(y_1) > b_2(y_2) = 3 + y_2\). Substituting the expected value \(b_1(y_1) = y_1 + 2\) results in player 1 bidding as follows: \[b_1(y_1) = y_1 + (5 - 3) = y_1 + 2\].
04

Limitation of Player Bids Due to Common Knowledge

Since no player will bid higher than their expected value of \(Y\) given \(y_i\) (creating a non-negative payoff), and both players know this fact, it implies that they will not bid above \(y_i + 5\). Thus, each player will set an upper bid limit at \(y_i + 5\).
05

Checking for Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Assume both players use the strategy \(b_i = y_i + z\). If \(z > 5\), the strategy results in a negative expected payoff for at least one player due to exceeding \(y_i + 5\), violating common knowledge of rational bidding. Hence, there cannot be a equilibrium where \(z>0\) because it encourages bids exceeding expected payout.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Common-Value Auction
In a common-value auction, the item's true value is the same for all bidders, but this value is not known with certainty until after the auction. Each player receives a private signal—a piece of information—that can help them estimate this true value. In our example, the auction value is stated as \(Y = y_1 + y_2\), where \(y_1\) and \(y_2\) are uniformly distributed between 0 and 10.
The challenge in a common-value auction is for each player to deduce the total value based on only partial information (their own signal) and to strategize their bid accordingly. It becomes a game of belief and estimation, where players must consider not only their own valuation but also what competitors might value and bid.
Bayesian Nash Equilibrium
A Bayesian Nash Equilibrium (BNE) extends the concept of Nash Equilibrium to scenarios where players have incomplete information about others, and make decisions based on their beliefs (often characterized by probability distributions). Each player chooses their best strategy given their information and beliefs about other players' strategies.
In our context, no BNE exists where players use strategies \(b_i = y_i + z\) if \(z > 0\). The reasoning is that any positive \(z\) forces a player to exceed their expected non-negative payoff threshold \(y_i + 5\), contradicting the rational behavior assumption in auction theory. The equilibrium requires each player's strategy to be a best response to the strategies of others, and with \(z > 0\), it generates a negative expected payoff for at least one of the players, breaking equilibrium conditions.
Expected Value
Expected value in this context is a statistical measure of the mean value of the auction's item as estimated by a player. For each player receiving a signal like \(y_1\), the expected value of \(Y\) given this information is calculated as \(E[Y|y_1] = y_1 + 5\), because \(y_2\) is uniformly distributed from 0 to 10 and thus has an average value of 5.
Using expected value helps each player set a rational bid that takes into account both their own valuation and a reasonable estimate of the opponent's signal. This is crucial, as the player aims to make a bid that is high enough to win, but not so high that it risks a negative payoff when the true value is revealed post-auction.
Bidding Strategies
When strategizing bids in a common-value auction, players need to balance between bidding high enough to win and ensuring a positive payoff. Given the opponent's strategy \(b_2(y_2) = 3 + y_2\), player 1 might choose a best-response strategy of \(b_1(y_1) = y_1 + 2\). This exploits the expected value and competitive bid effectively.
Strategically, players also must ensure that their bids never exceed \(y_i + 5\) to maintain non-negative payoffs. A higher bid than this expected value, suggested by the auction setup, leads to an unsustainable strategy, risking losses if the bid exceeds the actual common value after the fact. Crafting an optimal bidding strategy thus involves predicting opponent responses while ensuring maximum expected gain without overstepping fair value estimations.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Consider an "all-pay auction" with two players (the bidders). Player 1's valuation \(v_{1}\) for the object being auctioned is uniformly distributed between 0 and 1. That is, for any \(x \in[0,1]\), player 1's valuation is below \(x\) with probability \(x\). Player 2's valuation is also uniformly distributed between 0 and 1, so the game is symmetric. After nature chooses the players' valuations, each player observes his/her own valuation but not that of the other player. Simultaneously and independently, the players submit bids. The player who bids higher wins the object, but both players must pay their bids. That is, if player \(i\) bids \(b_{i}\), then his/her payoff is \(-b_{i}\) if he/she does not win the auction; his/her payoff is \(v_{i}-b_{i}\) if he/she wins the auction. Calculate the Bayesian Nash equilibrium strategies (bidding functions). (Hint: The equilibrium bidding function for player \(i\) is of the form \(b_{i}\left(v_{i}\right)=k v_{i}^{2}\) for some number \(k\).)

Complete the analysis of the second-price auction by showing that bidding one's valuation \(v_{i}\) is weakly preferred to bidding any \(x

Suppose you and one other bidder are competing in a private-value auction. The auction format is sealed bid, first price. Let \(v\) and \(b\) denote your valuation and bid, respectively, and let \(\hat{v}\) and \(\hat{b}\) denote the valuation and bid of your opponent. Your payoff is \(v-b\) if it is the case that \(b \geq \hat{b}\). Your payoff is 0 otherwise. Although you do not observe \(\hat{v}\), you know that \(\hat{v}\) is uniformly distributed over the interval between 0 and 1 . That is, \(v^{\prime}\) is the probability that \(\hat{v}

Consider a first-price auction with three bidders, whose valuations are independently drawn from a uniform distribution on the interval \([0,30]\). Thus, for each player \(i\) and any fixed number \(y \in[0,30], y / 30\) is the probability that player \(i\) 's valuation \(v_{i}\) is below \(y\). (a) Suppose that player 2 is using the bidding function \(b_{2}\left(v_{2}\right)=(3 / 4) v_{2}\), and player 3 is using the bidding function \(b_{3}\left(v_{3}\right)=(4 / 5) v_{3}\). Determine player 1's optimal bidding function in response. Start by writing player 1 's expected payoff as a function of player 1's valuation \(v_{1}\) and her bid \(b_{1}\). (b) Disregard the assumptions made in part (a). Calculate the Bayesian Nash equilibrium of this auction game and report the equilibrium bidding functions.

Suppose that you and two other people are competing in a third-price, sealed- bid auction. In this auction, players simultaneously and independently submit bids. The highest bidder wins the object but only has to pay the bid of the third-highest bidder. Sure, this is a silly type of auction, but it makes for a nice exercise. Suppose that your value of the object is 20 . You do not know the values of the other two bidders. Demonstrate that, in contrast with a second-price auction, it may be strictly optimal for you to bid 25 instead of 20 . Show this by finding a belief about the other players' bids under which 25 is a best-response action, yet 20 is not a best-response action.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free