Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose you and one other bidder are competing in a private-value auction. The auction format is sealed bid, first price. Let v and b denote your valuation and bid, respectively, and let v^ and b^ denote the valuation and bid of your opponent. Your payoff is vb if it is the case that bb^. Your payoff is 0 otherwise. Although you do not observe v^, you know that v^ is uniformly distributed over the interval between 0 and 1 . That is, v is the probability that \(\hat{v}

Short Answer

Expert verified
The optimal bid is 425.

Step by step solution

01

Understand the Auction Format

In a sealed-bid, first-price auction, each bidder submits a bid without knowing the other's bid, and the highest bid wins. The winning bidder pays the price they bid. Your payoff can be calculated as vb if you win (i.e., your bid b is greater than or equal to your opponent's bid b^), and 0 if you lose.
02

Calculate the Opponent's Bidding Strategy

Your opponent's bid is defined as b^(v^)=v^2. Knowing that v^ is uniformly distributed over the interval [0, 1], the probability that v^<v is simply v. Therefore, b^(v^) implies that your opponent's bid varies as the square of their valuation.
03

Determine Probability of Winning

To win, your bid b must be equal to or greater than your opponent's bid b^. From b^(v^)=v^2, you want to ensure bv^2. Given this setup, the probability that bb^ happens when v^2b, which means v^b. The probability is therefore b because v^ is uniform over [0,1].
04

Maximize Expected Payoff

Your expected payoff is (vb)×Probability of Winning, which translates to (vb)×b. For your value v=35, we need to maximize the function (35b)×b.
05

Differentiate and Solve for Optimal Bid

We differentiate the expected payoff function E(b)=(35b)b with respect to b, setting the derivative equal to zero to find the maximum:E(b)=b35b2b=0.Simplifying and solving this equation will provide the optimal bid.
06

Optimal Bid Calculation

Solving the equation from Step 5, we find two solutions but only the solution within the interval (0,1) is relevant. So, after calculations:b=(25)2=425. We reduce it to find that the optimal bid when your valuation is 35, keeping it consistent with your competitor's behavior.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Auction Theory
Auction theory is a fascinating field within economics that studies how people compete to buy or sell goods, services, or assets in an auction format. This field explores various elements that affect auction outcomes, such as the rules of bidding, the information available to bidders, and the payment model.

In a nutshell, auction theory applies principles from economics and game theory to understand how bidders behave in auctions and how different auction designs influence bidders' strategies and outcomes.
  • Types of auctions include English auctions, Dutch auctions, first-price sealed-bid auctions, and second-price sealed-bid auctions, each with unique rules and strategic implications.
  • Key considerations in auction theory are how auction rules affect bidder behavior and how they shape the final outcome.
  • A well-designed auction can lead to an efficient allocation of resources, where goods are sold at a price equal to their true valuation.
Understanding auction theory helps us predict human behavior in competitive bidding environments and allows for designing auctions to achieve specific goals.
Bidding Strategy
A bidding strategy is a planned approach a bidder takes to determine how much to bid in an auction. Developing an effective bidding strategy involves understanding the auction format, opponents' behavior, and the payoff structure.

In a first-price sealed-bid auction, like the one described in the exercise, bidders submit one bid in secret, and the highest bidder wins, paying their bid amount. This setup encourages bidders to balance bidding high (to win) with bidding low (to maximize surplus when they win).
  • Knowing your competition's bidding strategies is crucial. If your opponent bids based on their valuation squared, as in the solution, understanding this function is vital.
  • Bidders must consider the probability of winning versus the potential payoff and cost. This trade-off impacts how high or low they decide to bid.
  • It's important for bidders to not only calculate how others might bid but also to make these calculations keeping their own valuations at the core.
Ultimately, an optimal bidding strategy minimizes risk and maximizes potential returns by carefully planning bids.
Sealed-Bid Auction
In a sealed-bid auction, all bidders submit their bids without knowing the bids of others. This format introduces a layer of uncertainty compared to open auctions, as each bidder only knows their own valuation and has to guess others'.

The first-price sealed-bid auction, the focus of our exercise, is particularly strategic because the highest bid wins, but the winner pays the amount they bid. This means:
  • Bidders must find a balance between bidding high enough to win but not so high that there's no financial gain.
  • There's no chance to adjust bids based on competitors' actions or insights, so preparing a strategy based on assumptions about others' valuations is essential.
  • The auction format can lead to "bid shading," where a bidder submits a bid lower than their valuation to increase their payoff if they win.
This secrecy and one-shot nature make sealed-bid auctions complex but also fascinating, as they reveal different strategic elements of auction theory.
Expected Payoff
The expected payoff in an auction is the anticipated profit a bidder expects to earn from participating. It calculates the average outcome considering the probability of different scenarios occurring.

In our first-price sealed-bid auction scenario, the payoff for a bidder is their own valuation minus their bid, but only if they win. Hence, the expected payoff must take into account:
  • The probability of winning, which depends on the comparison between their bid and opponents' bids.
  • The actual payoff if the bid wins, calculated as the difference between valuation and bid.
  • In the exercise, the expected payoff function was (vb)×b, reflecting the probability that a bid wins (b) and the payoff from winning (vb).
Optimizing the expected payoff involves carefully choosing a bid that maximizes this function, balancing a decent probability of winning with the best possible financial outcome.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that a person (the "seller") wishes to sell a single desk. Ten people are interested in buying the desk: Ann, Bill, Colin, Dave, Ellen, Frank, Gale, Hal, Irwin, and Jim. Each of the potential buyers would derive some utility from owning the desk, and this utility is measured in dollar terms by the buyer's "value." The valuations of the 10 potential buyers are shown in the following table.  Ann  Bill  Colin  Dave  Ellen  Frank  Gale  Hal  Irwin  Jim 45539261267882706556 Each bidder knows his or her own valuation of owning the desk. Using the appropriate concepts of rationality, answer these questions: (a) If the seller holds a second-price, sealed-bid auction, who will win the auction and how much will this person pay? (b) Suppose that the bidders' valuations are common knowledge among them. That is, it is common knowledge that each bidder knows the valuations of all of the other bidders. Suppose that the seller does not observe the bidders' valuations directly and knows only that they are all between 0 and 100 . If the seller holds a first-price, sealed-bid auction, who will win the desk and how much will he or she have to pay? (Think about the Nash equilibrium in the bidding game. The analysis of this game is a bit different from the [more complicated] analysis of the first-price auction in this chapter because here the bidders know one another's valuations.) (c) Now suppose that the seller knows that the buyers' valuations are 45,53 , 92,61,26,78,82,70,65, and 56 , but the seller does not know exactly which buyer has which valuation. The buyers know their own valuations but not one another's valuations. Suppose that the seller runs the following auction: She first announces a reserve price p. Then simultaneously and independently the players select their bids; if a player bids below p, then this player is disqualified from the auction and therefore cannot win. The highest bidder wins the desk and has to pay the amount of his or her bid. This is called a "sealed-bid, first price auction with a reserve price." What is the optimal reserve price p for the seller to announce? Who will win the auction? And what will the winning bid be?

Consider a first-price auction with three bidders, whose valuations are independently drawn from a uniform distribution on the interval [0,30]. Thus, for each player i and any fixed number y[0,30],y/30 is the probability that player i 's valuation vi is below y. (a) Suppose that player 2 is using the bidding function b2(v2)=(3/4)v2, and player 3 is using the bidding function b3(v3)=(4/5)v3. Determine player 1's optimal bidding function in response. Start by writing player 1 's expected payoff as a function of player 1's valuation v1 and her bid b1. (b) Disregard the assumptions made in part (a). Calculate the Bayesian Nash equilibrium of this auction game and report the equilibrium bidding functions.

Complete the analysis of the second-price auction by showing that bidding one's valuation vi is weakly preferred to bidding any \(x

Suppose that you and two other people are competing in a third-price, sealed- bid auction. In this auction, players simultaneously and independently submit bids. The highest bidder wins the object but only has to pay the bid of the third-highest bidder. Sure, this is a silly type of auction, but it makes for a nice exercise. Suppose that your value of the object is 20 . You do not know the values of the other two bidders. Demonstrate that, in contrast with a second-price auction, it may be strictly optimal for you to bid 25 instead of 20 . Show this by finding a belief about the other players' bids under which 25 is a best-response action, yet 20 is not a best-response action.

Consider the two-bidder auction environment discussed in this chapter, where the bidders' values are independently drawn and distributed uniformly on the interval [0,900]. Demonstrate that, by setting a reserve price, the auctioneer can obtain an expected revenue that exceeds what he would expect from the standard first- and second-price auctions. You do not have to compute the optimal reserve price or the actual equilibrium strategies to answer this question.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free