Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

In Example 2.8 we examined the effect of a 20 -percent decline in copper demand on the price of copper, using the linear supply and demand curves developed in Section 2.6. Suppose the long-run price elasticity of copper demand were -0.75 instead of -0.5 a. Assuming, as before, that the equilibrium price and quantity are P=$3 per pound and Q=18mil lion metric tons per year, derive the linear demand curve consistent with the smaller elasticity. b. Using this demand curve, recalculate the effect of a 55-percent decline in copper demand on the price of copper.

Short Answer

Expert verified
The new demand function with an elasticity of -0.75 will be P=0.1111Q+1. The new price of copper following a 55% decrease in demand, according to the new demand function, is $1.9 per pound.

Step by step solution

01

Compute the new slope of the demand curve

Given that the price elasticity of copper demand Ep is -0.75, the formula for price elasticity of demand is denoted as Ep=(dQ/Q)/(dP/P), where dQ/Q is the percentage change in quantity demanded and dP/P is the percentage change in price. We can rearrange the formula for the slope of the demand curve which features the price P, quantity Q, and the price elasticity of demand Ep: slope=(P/EpQ). Substituting the given values we get: slope=(3/0.7518)=0.1111
02

Find the y-intercept of the demand curve

To find the y-intercept, we'll use the equilibrium point in the line equation P=slopeQ+intercept. By rearranging, the intercept equals to PslopeQ. Substituting the values we get: intercept=30.111118=1
03

Write down the new demand function

Now we have the slope and y-intercept, we can create the new linear demand curve which is P=0.1111Q+1
04

Calculate the new price given a 55% decrease in demand

A 55% decline in demand means that the new quantity demanded will be Q=18(10.55)=8.1 million metric tons. By inserting the new quantity in our derived demand function, we get a new price P=0.11118.1+1=1.9 dollars. Therefore, the price of copper following a 55% decrease in demand, given the new price elasticity of -0.75, is 1.9 dollars.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Linear Supply and Demand Curves
Understanding the basics of linear supply and demand curves is essential for analyzing market dynamics. These curves visually represent the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied or demanded at that price. For demand, the curve typically slopes downwards, indicating that as the price decreases, the quantity demanded increases. Conversely, for supply, the curve slopes upwards, suggesting that as the price increases, suppliers are willing to offer more of the good.

When we speak of a 'linear' relationship, it means that the graph of the supply or demand curve is a straight line. This implies a constant rate of change — the slope — which is rare in real-life scenarios but simplifies calculations and conceptual understanding. For example, if the demand curve for copper is linear, a consistent reduction in the price will lead to proportional increases in the quantity demanded.

To enhance this concept for students, demonstrating how changes in various factors shift these lines or affect their slopes provides practical insight into market behavior, such as how a subsidy affects supply or how consumer preference changes impact demand.
Equilibrium Price and Quantity
The point where the supply and demand curves intersect is known as the equilibrium price and quantity. At this point, the amount of goods that consumers are willing to buy equals the amount that producers are willing to sell. This is a state of balance where there is no inherent tendency for change—unless external factors disrupt the equilibrium.

In our example, the equilibrium price of copper is initially $3 per pound, and the equilibrium quantity is 18 million metric tons per year. These figures are crucial as they reflect the market's consensus on the value of copper. If there's a disturbance, like a change in demand, equilibrium will shift, changing both the price and quantity. A detailed understanding of this concept can help students predict how various market forces will influence prices and production levels over time.
Slope of the Demand Curve
The slope of the demand curve is a critical element in understanding consumer behavior. It measures the rate at which quantity demanded changes in response to a change in price. Mathematically, the slope is the ratio of the change in the price to the change in the quantity demanded.

In simplified terms, imagine you're climbing down a hill—the steeper the hill (or the curve), the more significant the change in elevation (or quantity demanded) for every step you take (change in price). A steeper demand curve means that a small change in price leads to a large change in the quantity demanded. In the provided solution, calculating the new slope of the demand curve is vital to determining both the demand curve's equation and how responsive consumers are to price changes.
Y-intercept of the Demand Curve
The y-intercept of the demand curve is the point on the graph where the demand curve crosses the y-axis. This intercept represents the price that consumers would pay if the quantity demanded was zero—a theoretical construct since it's uncommon for the quantity demanded to be zero.

The y-intercept is a starting point for plotting the demand curve and holds importance in the equation of the demand curve. For instance, let's say you're setting up a lemonade stand. Initially, regardless of price, you haven't sold any lemonade—this would be represented by the y-intercept. In the exercise, we derive a y-intercept value of 1. This value corresponds to the scenario without the effects of changes in the quantity—providing us with the baseline price from which to build our demand equation.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The rent control agency of New York City has found that aggregate demand is QD=1608P. Quantity is measured in tens of thousands of apartments. Price, the average monthly rental rate, is measured in hundreds of dollars. The agency also noted that the increase in Q at lower P results from more three-person families coming into the city from Long Island and demanding apartments. The city's board of realtors acknowledges that this is a good demand estimate and has shown that supply is Qs=70+7P a. If both the agency and the board are right about demand and supply, what is the free-market price? What is the change in city population if the agency sets a maximum average monthly rent of $300 and all those who cannot find an apartment leave the city? b. Suppose the agency bows to the wishes of the board and sets a rental of $900 per month on all apartments to allow landlords a "fair" rate of return. If 50 percent of any long-run increases in apartment offerings comes from new construction, how many apartments are constructed?

Example 2.9 (page 76 ) analyzes the world oil market. Using the data given in that example: a. Show that the short-run demand and competitive supply curves are indeed given by \[ D=36.750.035PSC=21.85+0.023P \] b. Show that the long-run demand and competitive supply curves are indeed given by \[ D=45.50.210PSC=16.1+0.138P \] c. In Example 2.9 we examined the impact on price of a disruption of oil from Saudi Arabia. Suppose that instead of a decline in supply, OPEC production increases by 2 billion barrels per year (bb/yr) because the Saudis open large new oil fields. Calculate the effect of this increase in production on the price of oil in both the short run and the long run.

In Example 2.8 (page 74 ), we discussed the recent decline in world demand for copper, due in part to China's decreasing consumption. What would happen, however, if China's demand were increasing? a. Using the original elasticities of demand and supply (i.e., Es=1.5 and ED=0.5), calculate the effect of a 20 -percent increase in copper demand on the price of copper. b. Now calculate the effect of this increase in demand on the equilibrium quantity, Q c. As we discussed in Example 2.8 , the U.S. production of copper declined between 2000 and 2003 Calculate the effect on the equilibrium price and quantity of both a 20 -percent increase in copper demand (as you just did in part a) and of a 20 -percent decline in copper supply.

Much of the demand for U.S. agricultural output has come from other countries. In 1998, the total demand for wheat was Q=3244283P. Of this, total domestic demand was QD=1700107P, and domestic supply was Qs=1944+207P. Suppose the export demand for wheat falls by 40 percent. a. U.S. farmers are concerned about this drop in export demand. What happens to the free-market price of wheat in the United States? Do farmers have much reason to worry? b. Now suppose the U.S. government wants to buy enough wheat to raise the price to $3.50 per bushel. With the drop in export demand, how much wheat would the government have to buy? How much would this cost the government?

In 2010, Americans smoked 315 billion cigarettes, or 15.75 billion packs of cigarettes. The average retail price (including taxes) was about $5.00 per pack. Statistical studies have shown that the price elasticity of demand is 0.4, and the price elasticity of supply is 0.5 a. Using this information, derive linear demand and supply curves for the cigarette market. b. In 1998, Americans smoked 23.5 billion packs of cigarettes, and the retail price was about $2.00 per pack. The decline in cigarette consumption from 1998 to 2010 was due in part to greater public awareness of the health hazards from smoking, but was also due in part to the increase in price. Suppose that the entire decline was due to the increase in price. What could you deduce from that about the price elasticity of demand?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free