Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Dayna's Doorstops, Inc. (DD) is a monopolist in the doorstop industry. Its cost is \(C=100-5 Q+Q^{2}\), and demand is \(P=55-2 Q\) a. What price should DD set to maximize profit? What output does the firm produce? How much profit and consumer surplus does DD generate? b. What would output be if \(D D\) acted like a perfect competitor and set \(\mathrm{MC}=P ?\) What profit and consumer surplus would then be generated? c. What is the deadweight loss from monopoly power in part (a)? d. Suppose the government, concerned about the high price of doorstops, sets a maximum price at \(\$ 27\) How does this affect price, quantity, consumer surplus, and DD's profit? What is the resulting deadweight loss? e. Now suppose the government sets the maximum price at \(\$ 23 .\) How does this decision affect price, quantity, consumer surplus, DD's profit, and deadweight loss? f. Finally, consider a maximum price of \(\$ 12 .\) What will this do to quantity, consumer surplus, profit, and deadweight loss?

Short Answer

Expert verified
The solutions would depend on the algebraic results of the prior steps. It covers various market scenarios, effects of government interference, and the resultant deadweight loss in each case.

Step by step solution

01

Monopoly Pricing

Here the first step is to find the profit maximizing quantity where Marginal Cost (MC) is equal to Marginal Revenue (MR) for a monopolist. MR is derived from the demand function and MC from the cost function. Then substitute the optimal quantity in the price function to find the monopolistic price. Consumer surplus can be calculated as half the product of quantity and difference between highest price consumers are willing to pay and monopolistic price. Profit is the difference between Total Revenue (TR) and Total Cost (TC).
02

Perfect Competition Pricing

In a perfect competition scenario, the firm sets its price equal to marginal cost. The output is determined by setting MC equal to price from demand function. After finding the optimal quantity, consumer surplus and profit can be calculated similarly as in Step 1.
03

Calculation of Deadweight Loss in Monopoly

Deadweight Loss refers to the economic inefficiency, in this case caused by monopoly pricing. It is calculated as the difference between the Consumer’s Surplus (CS) and Producer’s Surplus (PS) under perfect competition and monopoly.
04

Price Ceiling at $27

A price ceiling means the products cannot be sold at a price higher than the ceiling. Now set the price from demand function equal to $27 and solve for quantity. Then calculate the impact on price, quantity, consumer surplus, firm's profit and the resulting deadweight loss.
05

Price Ceiling at $23

Repeat step 4 but with the price ceiling now set at $23. Again, calculate the impacts.
06

Price Ceiling at $12

Finally, repeat step 4 but now with a price ceiling set at $12 and calculate the resulting quantity, consumer surplus, firm's profit and the deadweight loss.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Marginal Cost
When analyzing a company's pricing strategies, understanding marginal cost (MC) is critical. Marginal cost refers to the expense of producing one additional unit of a good. In economic terms, it's the slope of the total cost curve. Businesses use MC to determine the optimal level of production: they can increase production as long as the revenue from an additional unit exceeds the marginal cost of producing it.

For monopolists like Dayna's Doorstops, Inc. (DD), equating marginal cost to marginal revenue helps find the profit-maximizing output. This relationship is central to monopoly pricing strategy, as monopolists can adjust their output to influence market prices. In a competitive market, firms have less control and typically set prices equal to their marginal cost to remain competitive.
Marginal Revenue
Marginal revenue (MR) is the additional income from selling one more unit of a good. For monopolies, MR diminishes with each additional unit sold due to the downward sloping demand curve: to sell more, they must lower the price, which affects revenue from units they could have sold at a higher price. By contrast, in perfect competition, the price remains constant as firms are price takers, and thus marginal revenue equals the market price.

In the exercise, DD derives its marginal revenue from its demand curve and looks for the quantity where MR equals MC to maximize profits. Monopoly pricing strategies hinge on this balance, with monopolists manipulating output to manage scarcity and prices.
Deadweight Loss
Deadweight loss measures inefficiency in a market—value that is lost to consumers or producers because the market is not operating at an optimal point. Under perfect competition, markets tend to be efficient with minimal deadweight loss. In a monopoly, however, the monopolist sets the price above marginal cost, leading to reduced output and a higher price than in a competitive market. This results in a deadweight loss, which is the social cost of market inefficiency.

The exercise highlights how DD's monopoly generates deadweight loss by comparing hypothetical consumer and producer surplus in both monopoly and perfect competition scenarios. Knowing the size of deadweight loss can help governments decide on policies like price ceilings to correct inefficiencies.
Consumer Surplus
Consumer surplus is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good or service and what they actually pay. It serves as an indicator of the economic benefit to consumers, representing the area under the demand curve and above the market price. In the case of DD, consumer surplus is calculated by evaluating the area between the demand curve and the price DD sets for its doorstops.

A monopoly typically reduces consumer surplus as it restricts output and raises prices above marginal cost. As shown in the exercise, consumer surplus under a monopolistic scenario is less than what would have been under perfect competition—where the price equals MC.
Perfect Competition
In an ideal perfect competition market structure, numerous small firms compete, none having significant market power. Each firm in such a market is a price taker—they cannot influence market price, which is determined solely by supply and demand. Firms compete by setting their price equal to marginal cost.

The comparison analysis in the exercise shows that if DD would have acted like a firm under perfect competition, it would set the price equal to its marginal cost, resulting in a different quantity of output and consumer surplus than in the monopoly scenario. Perfect competition generally maximizes consumer surplus and minimizes deadweight loss, offering a stark contrast to the monopoly outcome.
Price Ceiling
A price ceiling is a government-imposed limit on how high a price can be set for a product. It is typically set below the equilibrium price in an attempt to make goods more affordable for consumers. In the exercise, the government sets price ceilings at \(27, \)23, and $12 to curb DD's monopoly pricing. Such interventions can increase consumer surplus by reducing prices and can potentially decrease deadweight loss.

When enforced, a price ceiling may lead to shortages if the ceiling is below the market-clearing price, as it discourages production. In the analysis of DD's situation, we see how different price ceiling levels have varying impacts on price, quantity, consumer surplus, DD's profit, and deadweight loss.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The employment of teaching assistants (TAs) by major universities can be characterized as a monopsony. Suppose the demand for TAs is \(W=30,000-125 n\) where \(W\) is the wage (as an annual salary) and \(n\) is the number of TAs hired. The supply of TAs is given by \(W\) \(=1000+75 n\) a. If the university takes advantage of its monopsonist position, how many TAs will it hire? What wage will it pay? b. If, instead, the university faced an infinite supply of TAs at the annual wage level of \(\$ 10,000,\) how many TAs would it hire?

Caterpillar Tractor, one of the largest producers of farm machinery in the world, has hired you to advise it on pricing policy. One of the things the company would like to know is how much a 5 -percent increase in price is likely to reduce sales. What would you need to know to help the company with this problem? Explain why these facts are important.

A monopolist faces the following demand curve: \\[ Q=144 / P^{2} \\] where \(Q\) is the quantity demanded and \(P\) is price. Its average variable cost is \\[ \mathrm{AVC}=Q^{1 / 2} \\] and its fixed cost is 5 a. What are its profit-maximizing price and quantity? What is the resulting profit? b. Suppose the government regulates the price to be no greater than \(\$ 4\) per unit. How much will the monopolist produce? What will its profit be? c. Suppose the government wants to set a ceiling price that induces the monopolist to produce the largest possible output. What price will accomplish this goal?

A firm faces the following average revenue (demand) curve: \\[ P=120-0.02 Q \\] where \(Q\) is weekly production and \(P\) is price, measured in cents per unit. The firm's cost function is given by \(C=\) \(60 Q+25,000 .\) Assume that the firm maximizes profits. a. What is the level of production, price, and total profit per week? b. If the government decides to levy a tax of 14 cents per unit on this product, what will be the new level of production, price, and profit?

A monopolist faces the demand curve \(P=11-Q\) where \(P\) is measured in dollars per unit and \(Q\) in thousands of units. The monopolist has a constant average \(\operatorname{cost}\) of \(\$ 6\) per unit. a. Draw the average and marginal revenue curves and the average and marginal cost curves. What are the monopolist's profit-maximizing price and quantity? What is the resulting profit? Calculate the firm's degree of monopoly power using the Lerner index b. A government regulatory agency sets a price ceiling of \(\$ 7\) per unit. What quantity will be produced, and what will the firm's profit be? What happens to the degree of monopoly power? c. What price ceiling yields the largest level of output? What is that level of output? What is the firm's degree of monopoly power at this price?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free