Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose the utility function for goods \(X\) and \(Y\) is given by \\[ \text { utility }=U(X, Y)=X Y+Y \\] a. Calculate the uncompensated (Marshallian) demand functions for \(X\) and \(Y\) and describe how the demand curves for \(X\) and \(Y\) are shifted by changes in \(I\) or in the price of the other good. b. Calculate the expenditure function for \(X\) and \(Y\). c. Use the expenditure function calculated in part (b) to compute the compensated demand functions for goods \(X\) and \(Y\). Describe how the compensated demand curves for \(X\) and \(Y\) are shifted by changes in income or by changes in the prices of the other good.

Short Answer

Expert verified
Question: Derive the Marshallian and Hicksian demand functions for the utility function \(U(X, Y) = XY + Y\), and explain how the demand curves are shifted for each. Answer: The Marshallian demand functions are: 1. \(X^M = \frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\) 2. \(Y^M = I - p_X \left(\frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\right)\) For the Marshallian demand curves, the change in demand for \(X\) or \(Y\) will be determined by changes in income (\(I\)) or in the price of the other good (\(p_X\) or \(p_Y\)). The Hicksian demand functions are: 1. \(X^H = \frac{E-\frac{p_Y^2 U}{p_X^2 + p_Y}}{p_X^2}\) 2. \(Y^H = E - p_X \left(\frac{E-\frac{p_Y^2 U}{p_X^2 + p_Y}}{p_X^2}\right)\) For the Hicksian demand curves, changes in income have no effect, but changes in the prices of the other goods would. An increase in \(p_Y\) would lead to a rightward shift in the compensated demand curve for \(X\), while a decrease in \(p_Y\) would lead to a leftward shift. An increase in \(p_X\) would lead to a leftward shift in the compensated demand curve for \(Y\), while a decrease in \(p_X\) would lead to a rightward shift.

Step by step solution

01

a. Uncompensated (Marshallian) demand functions for \(X\) and \(Y\)

First, we'll derive the Marshallian demands for \(X\) and \(Y\). Given the utility function \(U(X, Y) = XY + Y\), we will set up the Lagrangian: \( L = XY + Y + \lambda(I - p_X X - p_Y Y) \) To find the Marshallian demands, we'll get the first order conditions (FOCs) by taking the partial derivatives with respect to \(X\), \(Y\), and \(\lambda\): 1. \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial X} = Y - \lambda p_X\) 2. \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial Y} = X + 1 - \lambda p_Y\) 3. \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda} = I - p_X X - p_Y Y\) Now we solve the 2 first equations to obtain \(\lambda\), obtaining \(\lambda = \frac{Y}{p_X} = \frac{X + 1}{p_Y}\), so we have: \(Y = p_X (X + 1)\) or \(X = \frac{Y - p_X}{p_X}\) Substituting \(X\) in the budget constraint, we have: \(I - p_X X - p_Y Y = I - p_X\left(\frac{Y - p_X}{p_X}\right) - p_Y Y = 0\) \(I - p_Y(p_X + 1) = 0\) Solving this equation, we obtain the Marshallian demands: \(X^M = \frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\) \(Y^M = I - p_X \left(\frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\right)\) The change in the demand curve for \(X\) or \(Y\) will be determined by changes in income (\(I\)) or in the price of the other good (\(p_X\) or \(p_Y\)).
02

b. Expenditure function for \(X\) and \(Y\)

The expenditure function is calculated as the minimum amount of money spent to reach a given utility level \(U\). We can derive this by substituting the demand functions for \(X\) and \(Y\) into the budget constraint, and then solving for \(I\): \(E(p_X,p_Y,U) = p_X X^M + p_Y Y^M\) \(E(p_X,p_Y,U) = p_X \left(\frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\right) + p_Y \left(I - p_X \left(\frac{I - p_Y}{p_X^2}\right)\right)\) Now, we solve this equation for \(I\): \(I=E(p_X,p_Y,U)=\frac{p_Y^2 U}{p_X^2 + p_Y}\)
03

c. Compensated (Hicksian) demand functions for \(X\) and \(Y\)

To find the Hicksian demands, we need to find the optimal bundle (\(X^H\) and \(Y^H\)) that maximizes utility while keeping the expenditure fixed at the specific level \(E\). In order to do that, we replace \(I\) in the Marshallian demands by \(E(p_X, p_Y, U)\): \(X^H = \frac{E-\frac{p_Y^2 U}{p_X^2 + p_Y}}{p_X^2}\) \(Y^H = E - p_X \left(\frac{E-\frac{p_Y^2 U}{p_X^2 + p_Y}}{p_X^2}\right)\) Hicksian demand curves for \(X\) and \(Y\) will be shifted by changes in income or by changes in the prices of the other good. In this specific utility function, the Hicksian demands are not affected by changes in income, but are affected by changes in the prices of the other goods. The reasons are: - For \(X^H\), when \(p_Y\) increases, the denominator term \(p_X^2 + p_Y\) will increase as well, resulting in a higher overall value for \(X^H\), which means the compensated demand curve for \(X\) would shift rightward as the price for \(Y\) increases. Conversely, if \(p_Y\) decreases, the compensated demand curve for \(X\) would shift leftward. - For \(Y^H\), when \(p_X\) increases, the term inside the parenthesis in the second part will increase as well, resulting in a lower overall value for \(Y^H\), which means the compensated demand curve for \(Y\) would shift leftward as the price for \(X\) increases. Conversely, if \(p_X\) decreases, the compensated demand curve for \(Y\) would shift rightward.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

As defined in Chapter \(3,\) an indifference map is homothetic if any straight line through the origin cuts all indifference curves at points of equal slope: The \(M R S\) depends on the ratio \(Y / X\) a. Prove that in this case \(\partial X / \partial I\) is constant. b. Prove that if an individual's tastes can be represented by a homothetic indifference map, price and quantity must move in opposite directions; that is, prove that Giffen's paradox cannot occur.

Suppose that an inclividual's utility for \(X\) and \(Y\) is represented by the CES function (for \\[ \begin{array}{r} \delta=-1): \\ \text { utility }=U(X, Y)=-\frac{1}{X}-\frac{1}{Y} \end{array} \\] a. Use the Lagrangian multiplier method to calculate the uncompensated demand functions for \(X\) and \(Y\) for this function. b. Show that the demand functions calculated in part (a) are homogeneous of degree zero in \(P_{x}, P_{y},\) and \(I\) c. How do changes in \(I\) or in \(P_{y}\) shift the demand curve for good \(X\) ?

Show that if there are only two goods \((X \text { and } Y\) ) to choose from, both cannot be inferior goods. If \(X\) is inferior, how do changes in income affect the demand for \(Y ?\)

David N. gets \(\$ 3\) per week as an allowance to spend any way he pleases. Because he likes only peanut butter and jelly sandwiches, he spends the entire amount on peanut butter (at \(\$ .05\) per ounce) and jelly (at \(\$ .10\) per ounce). Bread is provided free of charge by a concerned neighbor. David is a particular eater and makes his sandwiches with exactly 1 ounce of jelly and 2 ounces of peanut butter. He is set in his ways and will never change these proportions. a. How much peanut butter and jelly will David buy with his \(\$ 3\) allowance in a week? b. Suppose the price of jelly were to rise to \(\$ .15\) an ounce. How much of each commodity would be bought? c. By how much should David's allowance be increased to compensate for the rise in the price of jelly in part (b)? d Graph your results in parts (a) to (c). e. In what sense does this problem involve only a single commodity, peanut butter and jelly sandwiches? Graph the demand curve for this single commodity. f. Discuss the results of this problem in terms of the income and substitution effects involved in the demand for jelly.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free