Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose a monopolist produces alkaline batteries that may have various useful lifetimes \((X) .\) Suppose also that consumers' (inverse) demand depends on batteries' lifetimes and quantity (Q) purchased according to the function \\[ P(Q, X)=g(X \cdot Q) \\] where \(g^{\prime}<0 .\) That is, consumers care only about the product of quantity times lifetime. They are willing to pay equally for many short-lived batteries or few long-lived ones. Assume also that battery costs are given by \\[ C(Q, X)=C(X) Q \\] where \(C^{\prime}(X)>0 .\) Show that in this case the monopoly will opt for the same level of \(X\) as does a competitive industry even though levels of output and prices may differ. Explain your result. (Hint: Treat \(X Q\) as a composite commodity.)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Yes, the monopolist and competitive industry will choose the same level of lifetime (X) for the batteries, even though their output and price might be different. This is because both types of firms would choose the level of lifetime that balances the trade-off between the higher revenue from increasing the lifetime (X) and the higher cost of improving the battery's quality, which depends only on the batteries' qualities and not on the market structure.

Step by step solution

01

To find the equilibrium for the monopolist, we need to write their profit maximization problem. The profit function for the monopolist can be written as: \(\Pi(Q, X) = P(Q, X)Q - C(Q, X)\) =

\(\Pi(Q, X) = g(XQ)Q - C(X)Q\) Now we need to find the optimal values of \(Q\) and \(X\) that maximize the profit function. #Step 2: Find the First Order Conditions for the Monopolist's Profit Maximization Problem#
02

We will need to find the partial derivatives of the profit function with respect to \(Q\) and \(X\), so that we can set them equal to 0 and solve for the maximization problem's first-order conditions. \(\frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial Q} = g'(XQ)XQ + g(XQ) - C(X) = 0\) \(\frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial X} = g'(XQ)Q^2 - C'(X)Q = 0\) After obtaining the first-order conditions, we'll proceed to solve them for \(Q\) and \(X\). #Step 3: Solve the First Order Conditions for the Monopolist's Optimal Choice of X#

We'll now solve the first-order conditions for \(Q\) and \(X\). We can use the second equation to express \(C'(X)\): \(C'(X) = g'(XQ)Q\) We know that \(g'<0\) and \(C'(X)>0\), therefore the choice of \(X\) must be such that \(g'(XQ)Q\) is positive. In other words, the monopolist will choose \(X\) in such a way that the marginal cost reduction due to lifetime improvement is equal to the marginal revenue reduction due to a higher product of quantity and lifetime. This is the monopolist's optimal choice of \(X\). #Step 4: Formulate the Profit Maximization Problem for the Competitive Industry#
03

Now, let's find the equilibrium for the competitive industry. In a competitive market, each firm's price is equal to the marginal cost of production, hence: \(P(Q, X) = C'(X)\) Substitute the inverse demand function: \(g(XQ) = C'(X)\) #Step 5: Comparing the Monopolist's and Competitive Industry's Choices of X#

Comparing the two equilibria, we can observe that both the monopolist and the competitive firms have the same condition for their choice of \(X\): \(g'(XQ)Q = C'(X)\) This implies that the monopolist and the competitive industry will produce at the same level of \(X\) even though their output and price might be different. The reason behind this result is that both types of firms would choose the level of lifetime for their batteries that balances the trade-off between the higher revenue from increasing the lifetime \((X)\) and the higher cost of improving the battery's quality. Since this trade-off depends only on the batteries' qualities and not on the market structure, the optimal choice of \(X\) is the same for both the monopolist and competitive firms.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Monopoly
A monopoly exists when a single firm dominates the entire market for a particular product or service. Unlike competitive markets with many sellers, a monopolistic market has only one provider who can significantly influence prices and output levels.
This means the monopolist can set prices higher than what would prevail under perfect competition, often leading to greater profits. However, monopolies face certain constraints, such as demand elasticity and costs of production, which influence their pricing and production decisions.
In the context of alkaline batteries, our monopolist must consider how changing the lifetime of the batteries \(X\) impacts consumer demand, taking advantage of their ability to influence prices.
Competitive Industry
A competitive industry comprises many firms, each producing a similar product, leading to a situation where no single firm can influence market price.
In such industries, firms are price takers, meaning they must accept the market price as given. Their goal is to produce where price equals marginal cost (MC), maximizing efficiency.
For the competitive industry producing batteries, the equilibrium condition is when the price of batteries equals the marginal cost of producing them. Unlike monopolies, competitive firms cannot set prices above this level as they would lose customers to competitors. This competitive dynamic prompts firms to be more efficient and innovative.
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost (MC) is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of a good. It plays a crucial role in decision-making for both monopolies and competitive firms.
For the monopolist in our problem, the decision on battery lifetime involves balancing the added cost of this improvement with the potential revenue benefits.
In the profit maximization condition, the monopolist sets the marginal cost of improving battery lifetime equal to the marginal revenue obtained from it.
  • In competitive industries, firms produce where their price equals marginal cost, ensuring no extra costs exceed the revenue from selling one more unit.
  • This ensures that resources are used efficiently, benefiting consumers with better prices and product quality.
Inverse Demand Function
The inverse demand function describes how the price of a good is related to its quantity demanded. It is a crucial tool for analyzing consumer behavior and setting optimal prices.
The demand for batteries in this scenario is based on a function that considers the total product of quantity and lifetime \(X \cdot Q\). This reflects consumers' preferences for either numerous short-lived batteries or fewer long-lived ones.
For a monopolist, understanding this relationship helps inform strategic decisions about production quantities and battery lifetimes, crucial for profit maximization. In competitive industries, the inverse demand function helps firms understand market dynamics and respond accordingly to consumer needs.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose the government wished to combat the undesirable allocation effects of a monopoly through the use of a subsidy. a. Why would a lump-sum subsidy not achieve the government's goal? b. Use a graphical proof to show how a per-unit-of-output subsidy might achieve the government's goal. c. Suppose the government wishes its subsidy to maximize the difference between the total value of the good to consumers and the good's total cost. Show that to achieve this goal it should set \\[ \frac{t}{P}=-\frac{1}{e_{Q, P}} \\] where \(t\) is the per-unit subsidy and \(P\) is the competitive price. Explain your result intuitively.

A monopolist faces a market demand curve given by \\[Q=70-P\\] a. If the monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \(A C=M C=6\) what output level will the monopolist choose in order to maximize profits? What is the price at this output level? What are the monopolist's profits? b. Assume instead that the monopolist has a cost structure where total costs are described by \\[T C=.25 Q^{2}-5 Q+300\\] With the monopolist facing the same market demand and marginal revenue, what price quantity combination will be chosen now to maximize profits? What will profits be? c. Assume now that a third cost structure explains the monopolist's position, with total costs given by \\[T C=.0133 Q^{3}-5 Q+250\\] Again, calculate the monopolist's price-quantity combination that maximizes profits. What will profit be? (Hint: Set \(M C=M R\) as usual and use the quadratic formula to solve the second-order equation for \(Q\) d. Graph the market demand curve, the \(M R\) curve, and the three marginal cost curves from parts \((\mathrm{a}),(\mathrm{b}),\) and \((\mathrm{c}) .\) Notice that the monopolist's profit-making ability is constrained by (1) the market demand curve (along with its associated \(M R\) curve) and (2) the cost structure underlying production.

Suppose a perfectly competitive industry can produce widgets at a constant marginal cost of \(\$ 10\) per unit. Monopolized marginal costs rise to \(\$ 12\) per unit because \(\$ 2\) per unit must be paid to lobbyists to retain the widget producers' favored position. Suppose the market demand for widgets is given by \\[ Q_{0}=1,000-50 P \\] a. Calculate the perfectly competitive and monopoly outputs and prices. b. Calculate the total loss of consumer surplus from monopolization of widget production. c. Graph your results and explain how they differ from the usual analysis.

A single firm monopolizes the entire market for widgets and can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \\[ A C=M C=10 \\] Originally, the firm faces a market demand curve given by \\[ Q=60-P \\] a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the firm. What are the firm's profits? b. Now assume that the market demand curve shifts outward (becoming stccper) and is given by \\[ Q=45-.5 P \\] What is the firm's profit-maximizing price-quantity combination now? What are the firm's profits? c. Instead of the assumptions of part (b), assume that the market demand curve shifts outward (becoming flatter) and is given by \\[ Q=100-2 P \\] What is the firm's profit-maximizing price-quantity combination now? What are the firm's profits? d. Graph the three different situations of parts (a), (b), and (c). Using your results, explain why there is no real supply curve for a monopoly.

Suppose a monopoly produces its output in several different plants and that these plants have differing cost structures. How should the firm decide how much total output to produce? How should it distribute this output among its plants to maximize profits?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free