Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Investment in risky assets can be examined in the state-preference framework by assuming that \(W^{*}\) dollars invested in an asset with a certain return, \(r,\) will yield \(\mathrm{W}^{*}(\mathrm{l}+r)\) in both states of the world, whereas investment in a risky asset will yield \(\mathrm{W}^{*}\left(1+r_{g}\right)\) in good times and \(\left.\mathrm{W}^{*}\left(\mathrm{l}+r_{b}\right) \text { in bad times (where } r_{g}>r>r_{b}\right)\) a. Graph the outcomes from the two investments. b. Show how a "mxied portfolio" containing both risk-free and risky assets could be illustrated in your graph. How would you show the fraction of wealth invested in the risky asset? c. Show how individuals' attitudes toward risk will determine the mix of risk- free and risky assets they will hold. In what case would a person hold no risky assets? d. If an individual's utility takes the constant relative risk aversion form (Equation 8.62 ), ex plain why this person will not change the fraction of risky asset held as his or her wealth increases.

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: An individual's risk preferences play a significant role in determining the mix of risk-free and risky assets in their investment portfolio. Risk-averse individuals will prefer to invest more in risk-free assets to minimize potential losses, while risk-seeking individuals will allocate a higher proportion of their portfolio to risky assets in the hope of higher returns. The investment decisions of someone with constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility remain unchanged as their wealth increases, as their risk preferences remain constant.

Step by step solution

01

a. Graph the outcomes of investing in risky and risk-free assets

To graph the outcomes of investing in risky and risk-free assets, let's first represent the return of each investment on the y-axis and the amount invested in each asset on the x-axis. For the risk-free asset, its return will be a straight line with a slope of \((1+r)\), while the risky asset will have two possible returns \((1+r_g)\) and \((1+r_b)\). We can plot these lines on a graph with appropriate labels for clarity.
02

b. Mixed portfolio illustration on the graph

To illustrate a mixed portfolio on the graph, we can show a combination of both risk-free and risky assets by creating an additional line that represents the returns of the mixed portfolio. This line will lie between the risk-free and risky asset lines as it takes on characteristics of both investments. We can represent the fraction of wealth invested in the risky asset by the slopes of the lines emanating from the point of intersection of the risk-free and risky asset lines. The lines with greater slope indicate a higher proportion of risky assets, whereas lines with lower slopes have a higher proportion of risk-free assets.
03

c. Individual attitudes toward risk and asset mix

Individuals' attitudes towards risk will determine the mix of risk-free and risky assets they hold. Risk-averse individuals will prefer to invest more in risk-free assets to minimize their exposure to potential losses. Conversely, risk-seeking individuals will allocate a higher proportion of their portfolio to risky assets in the hope of higher returns. In the extreme case, a person would hold no risky assets if they are entirely risk-averse, meaning they would only invest in the risk-free asset to avoid any significant losses.
04

d. Constant relative risk aversion and investment decisions

If an individual's utility takes the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) form, as given in Equation 8.62, their investment behavior is invariant to an increase in wealth. This is because the risk preferences of a person with constant relative risk aversion remain constant as their wealth increases. As a result, someone with CRRA utility will not change their investment decisions (i.e., the fraction of risky assets held in their portfolio) as their wealth increases. This is because their risk preferences remain the same despite an increase in wealth, and their preference for a balance between risk-free and risky assets remains unchanged.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Investment in Risky Assets
Understanding how to invest in risky assets is essential for any financial portfolio management. A risky asset is one that has variability in returns; it can yield higher gains in certain scenarios (referred to as 'good times') and losses in others ('bad times'). In contrast, a risk-free asset offers a certain return with no variability. When plotting these on a graph, as seen in step 1 of our exercise solution, the risk-free asset appears as a straight line, reflecting its stable return, while the risky asset shows two different outcomes, depicting potential fluctuations in returns.

Investors must consider their risk tolerance when deciding how much to invest in such assets. While some individuals may accept the higher risk for a chance at better returns, others may opt for a smaller allocation towards risky assets to preserve their capital. This exercise allows us to visualize the outcomes of different investment decisions and better understand the implications of adding risk to our portfolios.
Mixed Portfolio
A mixed portfolio, as explained in step 2 of our solution, involves diversification through combining both risk-free and risky assets. By balancing between the two, investors can tailor their portfolios to meet their risk preferences and investment objectives. On a graph, a mixed portfolio is represented by a line that demonstrates a blend of the characteristics of risk-free and risky assets. The slope of this line helps to indicate the fraction of wealth invested in the risky asset.

Determining the right mix depends on an investor's risk tolerance. An ideal mixed portfolio strikes a balance that maximizes returns while maintaining an acceptable level of risk exposure. This concept reflects the very essence of portfolio theory, illustrating how diversification can optimize investment outcomes.
Constant Relative Risk Aversion
Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) is a key measurement of how an investor's willingness to take risks remains unchanged, despite variations in wealth. According to the step 4 explanation, an individual with CRRA maintains a constant attitude towards risk, which implies that they do not alter the proportion of their investment in risky assets as their wealth grows.

For individuals conforming to CRRA, their risk tolerance is scaled to their overall wealth. As such, a proportional investment strategy is employed—using the same percentage of wealth to invest in risky assets irrespective of the total capital they hold. This utility function helps explain why some investors maintain a steady investment strategy, regardless of how much money they have or make, highlighting a fundamental principle of behavioral finance.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Blue-eyed people are more likely to lose their expensive watches than are brown-eyed people. Specifically, there is an 80 percent probability that a blue-eyed individual will lose a \(\$ 1,000\) watch during a year, but only a 20 percent probability that a brown-eyed person will. Blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally represented in the population. a. If an insurance company assumes blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally likely to buy watch-loss insurance, what will the actuarially fair insurance premium be? b. If blue-eyed and brown-eyed people have logarithmic utility-of-wealth functions and cur rent wealths of \(\$ 10,000\) each, will these individuals buy watch insurance at the premium calculated in part (a)? c. Given your results from part (b), will the insurance premiums be correctly computed? What should the premium be? What will the utility for each type of person be? d. Suppose that an insurance company charged different premiums for blue-eyed and brown-eyed people. How would these individuals' maximum utilities compare to those computed in parts (b) and (c)? (This problem is an example of adverse selection in insurance.)

In Problem \(8.5,\) Ms. Fogg was quite willing to buy insurance against a 25 percent chance of losing \(\$ 1,000\) of her cash on her around-the-world trip. Suppose that people who buy such insurance tend to become more careless with their cash and that their probability of losing \(\$ 1,000\) rises to 30 percent. What is the actuarially fair insurance premium in this situation? Will Ms. Fogg buy insurance now? (Note: This problem and Problem 9.3 illustrate moral hazard.)

Suppose there are two types of workers, high-ability workers and low-ability workers. Workers' wages are determined by their ability- high ability workers earn \(\$ 50,000\) per year, low ability workers earn \(\$ 30,000 .\) Firms cannot measure workers' abilities but they can observe whether a worker has a high school diploma. Workers' utility depends on the difference between their wages and the costs they incur in obtaining a diploma. a. If the cost of obtaining a high school diploma is the same for high-ability and low-ability workers, can there be a separating equilibrium in this situation in which high-ability workers get high-wage jobs and low-ability workers get low wages? b. What is the maximum amount that a high-ability worker would pay to obtain a high school diploma? Why must a diploma cost more than this for a low-ability person if having a diploma is to permit employers to identify high-ability workers?

An individual purchases a dozen eggs and must take them home. Although making trips home is costless, there is a 50 percent chance that all of the eggs carried on any one trip will be broken during the trip. The individual considers two strategies: Strategy 1: Take all 12 eggs in one trip. Strategy 2: Take two trips with 6 in each trip. a. List the possible outcomes of each strategy and the probabilities of these outcomes. Show that on the average, 6 eggs will remain unbroken after the trip home under either strategy. b. Develop a graph to show the utility obtainable under each strategy. Which strategy will be preferable? c. Could utility be improved further by taking more than two trips? How would this possi bility be affected if additional trips were costly?

For the constant relative risk aversion utility function (Equation 8.62 ) we showed that the degree of risk aversion is measured by \((1-R)\). In Chapter 3 we showed that the elasticity of substitution for the same function is given by \(1 /(1-R) .\) Hence, the measures are reciprocals of each other. Using this result, discuss the following questions: a. Why is risk aversion related to an individual's willingness to substitute wealth between states of the world? What phenomenon is being captured by both concepts? b. How would you interpret the polar cases \(R=1\) and \(R--^{\circ}\) in both the risk-aversion and substitution frameworks? c. A rise in the price of contingent claims in "bad" times \(\left(P_{b}\right)\) will induce substitution and income effects into the demands for \(W_{g}\) and \(W_{h}\). If the individual has a fixed budget to devote to these two goods, how will choices among them be affected? Why might \(W_{g}\) rise or fall depending on the degree of risk aversion exhibited by the individual? d. Suppose that empirical data suggest an individual requires an average return of 0.5 per cent if he or she is to be tempted to invest in an investment that has a \(50-50\) chance of gaining or losing 5 percent. That is, this person gets the same utility from \(W_{o}\) as from an even bet on \(1.055 W_{o}\) and \(0.955 W_{o}\) i. What value of \(R\) is consistent with this behavior? ii. How much average return would this person require to accept a \(50-50\) chance of gaining or losing 10 percent? Note: This part requires solving nonlinear equations, so approximate solutions will suffice. The comparison of the risk/reward trade-off illustrates what is called the "equity premium puzzle," in that risky investments seem to actually earn much more than is consistent with the degree of risk-aversion suggested by other data. See N. R. Kocherlakota, "The Equity Premium: It's Still a Puzzle" Journal of Economic Literature (March 1996 ): \(42-71\)

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free