Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose Molly Jock wishes to purchase a high-definition television to watch the Olympic Greco-Roman wrestling competition. Her current income is \(\$ 20,000,\) and she knows where she can buy the television she wants for \(\$ 2,000\). She has heard the rumor that the same set can be bought at Crazy Eddie's (recently out of bankruptcy) for \(\$ 1,700,\) but is unsure if the rumor is true. Suppose this individual's utility is given by \\[\text { utility }=\ln (Y).\\] where Fis her income after buying the television. a. What is Molly's utility if she buys from the location she knows? b. What is Molly's utility if Crazy Eddie's really does offer the lower price? c. Suppose Molly believes there is a \(50-50\) chance that Crazy Eddie does offer the lowerpriced television, but it will cost her \(\$ 100\) to drive to the discount store to find out for sure (the store is far away and has had its phone disconnected). Is it worth it to her to invest the money in the trip?

Short Answer

Expert verified
a. If Molly buys the television for $2,000, her income after purchase is $18,000. Her utility for this option is: $$utility_a = \ln(18000)$$ b. If Molly buys the television from Crazy Eddie's for $1,700, her income after purchase is $18,300. Her utility for this option is: $$utility_b = \ln(18300)$$ c. If Molly spends $100 to find out about Crazy Eddie's, she has a 50% chance to save $300 or buy the television at the original price. Her expected income is $18,050, and her expected utility is: $$Expected\,Utility = \ln(18,050)$$ To determine if it's worth investing $100, compare the expected utility to the utility of buying from the known location. If the expected utility is greater than the utility of buying from the known location, it's worth investing $100 to find out about Crazy Eddie's.

Step by step solution

01

a. Calculate utility for buying television from known location

If Molly buys the television for \(2,000\), she will have an income after purchase: \(Y_a = 20000 - 2000 = 18000\). Now, we can find her utility: \(utility_a = \ln(Y_a) = \ln(18000)\).
02

b. Calculate utility for buying television from Crazy Eddie's

If Molly buys at Crazy Eddie's for \(1,700\), her income after purchase will be: \(Y_b = 20000 - 1700 = 18300\). Let's find her utility in this case: \(utility_b = \ln(Y_b) = \ln(18300)\).
03

c. Analyze if it's worth investing $100 to find out about Crazy Eddie's

If Molly spends \(100\) to find out about Crazy Eddie's, she has \(50\%\) chance to either save \(300\) or end up buying the television for the original price. The expected income from this decision is: $$Expected\,Income = 0.5*(20,000 - 100 - 1,700) + 0.5*(20,000 - 100 - 2,000)$$ $$Expected\,Income = 0.5*(18,200) + 0.5*(17,900) = 18,050$$ Now calculate the expected utility: $$Expected\,Utility = \ln(18,050)$$ Now, compare the expected utility to the utility of buying from the known location: If \(Expected\,Utility > Utility_a\), then it is worth investing the \(100\) to find out about Crazy Eddie's.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Consumer Decision-Making
Understanding how consumers make decisions is a fundamental aspect of microeconomic theory. It encompasses the processes consumers use to choose among different options and allocate their limited resources optimally.

In the case of Molly Jock, we observe consumer decision-making in action. Molly is faced with a choice: purchase a high-definition television from a known location or investigate a potential deal at Crazy Eddie's, which carries inherent uncertainties and costs. Her decision will be guided by two main factors: the price of the television and her resulting utility or satisfaction derived from the purchase.

This process often involves predicting the outcomes of various choices, weighing the costs and benefits, and considering the risks involved. Molly's decision to either buy the television at the known price or spend additional resources to potentially secure a better deal reflects the complexities that consumers face in everyday purchase decisions.
Utility Function
A utility function is a mathematical representation of how a consumer ranks different bundles of goods based on the level of satisfaction or happiness that they provide. Essentially, it translates personal preferences into a quantifiable form that can be analyzed and compared.

In the exercise, Molly's utility function is defined as the natural logarithm of her income after purchasing the television, \( \text{utility} = \(ln(Y) \) \). This suggests that her utility is tied directly to how much money she retains after the purchase, which is a common assumption in many microeconomic models that deal with income and consumption.

The utility function can take various forms, but the natural logarithm is frequently used in economics due to its mathematical properties, such as reflecting diminishing marginal utility – the principle that as one consumes more of a good, the added satisfaction tends to decrease.
Expected Utility Theory
Expected utility theory is an important concept in economics that deals with the decision-making under uncertainty. It involves calculating the expected value of utility across different possible outcomes, giving weight to each based on its probability.

For Molly, the expected utility theory helps her determine if it's worth the risk and cost of driving to Crazy Eddie's. She considers the possible outcomes (finding the cheaper price or not) and their probabilities (50-50 in this case). By taking the expected income from these scenarios and plugging them into her utility function, she can determine the expected utility of taking the risk.

If this expected utility is higher than the utility of buying the television at the known price, the theory suggests it is rational for her to take the chance. This principle extends to various real-life situations, guiding consumers in making choices that maximize their expected level of satisfaction based on their preferences and the uncertainties involved.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

In some cases individuals may care about the date at which the uncertainty they face is resolved. Suppose, for example, that an individual knows that his or her consumption will be 10 units today \((Q)\) but that tomorrow's consumption \(\left(\mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\) will be either 10 or \(2.5,\) depending on whether a coin comes up heads or tails. Suppose also that the individual's utility function has the simple Cobb-Douglas form \\[U\left(Q, C_{2}\right)=V^{\wedge} Q.\\] a. If an individual cares only about the expected value of utility, will it matter whether the coin is flipped just before day 1 or just before day \(2 ?\) Explain. More generally, suppose that the individual's expected utility depends on the timing of the coin flip. Specifically, assume that \\[\text { expected utility }=\mathbf{f}^{\wedge}\left[\left(\mathrm{fi}\left\\{17\left(\mathrm{C}, \mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\right\\}\right) \text { ) } \text { ? } |\right.\\] where \(E_{x}\) represents expectations taken at the start of day \(1, E_{2}\) represents expectations at the start of day \(2,\) and \(a\) represents a parameter that indicates timing preferences. Show that if \(a=1,\) the individual is indifferent about when the coin is flipped. Show that if \(a=2,\) the individual will prefer early resolution of the uncertainty - that is, flipping the coin at the start of day 1 Show that if \(a=.5,\) the individual will prefer later resolution of the uncertainty (flipping at the start of day 2 ). Explain your results intuitively and indicate their relevance for information theory. (Note: This problem is an illustration of "resolution seeking" and "resolution-averse" behavior. See D. M. Kreps and E. L. Porteus, "Temporal Resolution of Uncertainty and Dynamic Choice Theory," Econometrica [January \(1978]: 185-200\).

In Problem \(8.5,\) Ms. Fogg was quite willing to buy insurance against a 25 percent chance of losing \(\$ 1,000\) of her cash on her around-the-world trip. Suppose that people who buy such insurance tend to become more careless with their cash and that their probability of losing \(\$ 1,000\) rises to 30 percent. What is the actuarially fair insurance premium in this situation? Will Ms. Fogg buy insurance now? (Note: This problem and Problem 9.3 illustrate moral hazard.)

Suppose there are two types of workers, high-ability workers and low-ability workers. Workers' wages are determined by their ability- high ability workers earn \(\$ 50,000\) per year, low ability workers earn \(\$ 30,000 .\) Firms cannot measure workers' abilities but they can observe whether a worker has a high school diploma. Workers' utility depends on the difference between their wages and the costs they incur in obtaining a diploma. a. If the cost of obtaining a high school diploma is the same for high-ability and low-ability workers, can there be a separating equilibrium in this situation in which high-ability workers get high-wage jobs and low-ability workers get low wages? b. What is the maximum amount that a high-ability worker would pay to obtain a high school diploma? Why must a diploma cost more than this for a low-ability person if having a diploma is to permit employers to identify high-ability workers?

A farmer believes there is a \(50-50\) chance that the next growing season will be abnormally rainy. His expected utility function has the form \\[ \begin{array}{c} \mathbf{1} \\ \text { expected utility }=-\boldsymbol{I} \boldsymbol{n} \boldsymbol{Y}_{N R}+-\boldsymbol{I} \boldsymbol{n} \boldsymbol{Y}_{R} \end{array} \\] where \(Y_{N R}\) and \(Y_{R}\) represent the farmer's income in the states of "normal rain" and "rainy," respectively. a. Suppose the farmer must choose between two crops that promise the following income prospects: $$\begin{array}{lcr} \text { Crop } & Y_{H} & Y_{R} \\ \hline \text { Wheat } & \$ 28,000 & \$ 10,000 \\ \text { Corn } & 19,000 & 15,000 \end{array}$$ Which of the crops will he plant? b. Suppose the farmer can plant half his field with each crop. Would he choose to do so? Explain your result. c. What mix of wheat and corn would provide maximum expected utility to this farmer? d. Would wheat crop insurance, available to farmers who grow only wheat, which costs \(\$ 4000\) and pays off \(\$ 8000\) in the event of a rainy growing season, cause this farmer to change what he plants?

A farmer's tomato crop is wilting, and he must decide whether to water it. If he waters the tomatoes, or if it rains, the crop will yield \(\$ 1,000\) in profits; but if the tomatoes get no water, they will yield only \(\$ 500 .\) Operation of the farmer's irrigation system costs \(\$ 100 .\) The farmer seeks to maximize expected profits from tomato sales. a. If the farmer believes there is a 50 percent chance of rain, should he water? b. What is the maximum amount the farmer would pay to get information from an itiner ant weather forecaster who can predict rain with 100 percent accuracy? c. How would your answer to part (b) change if the forecaster were only 75 percent accurate?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free