Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Ms. Fogg is planning an around-the-world trip on which she plans to spend \(\$ 10,000\). The utility from the trip is a function of how much she actually spends on it \((Y),\) given by \\[ U(Y)=\ln Y \\] a. If there is a 25 percent probability that Ms. Fogg will lose \(\$ 1000\) of her cash on the trip, what is the trip's expected utility? b. Suppose that Ms. Fogg can buy insurance against losing the \(\$ 1000\) (say, by purchasing traveler's checks) at an "actuarially fair" premium of \(\$ 250 .\) Show that her expected utility is higher if she purchases this insurance than if she faces the chance of losing the \(\$ 1000\) without insurance. c. What is the maximum amount that Ms. Fogg would be willing to pay to insure her \(\$ 1000 ?\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Based on the given information, we followed these steps to find the solution: 1. Calculate the expected utility without insurance. 2. Calculate the expected utility with insurance. 3. Compare expected utilities to determine if insurance is beneficial. 4. Find the maximum amount Ms. Fogg would be willing to pay for insurance. By comparing the expected utilities, we determined if purchasing insurance was beneficial for Ms. Fogg. After calculating the maximum amount she would be willing to pay, we found the point at which she would be indifferent between purchasing insurance or not.

Step by step solution

01

Expected Utility without Insurance

First, calculate the expected utility without insurance, which considers two situations: 1. Ms. Fogg loses \(1000: With a 25% probability, she will spend \)9,000. The utility of this situation is \(U(9000) = \ln{9000}\). 2. Ms. Fogg does not lose any money (75% probability), and she will spend \(10,000. The utility of this situation is \)U(10000)=\ln{10000}$. To find the expected utility, we gather the probabilities and the utility of each situation: Expected Utility (without insurance) = \(0.25 \cdot \ln{9000} + 0.75 \cdot \ln{10000}\).
02

Expected Utility with Insurance

Now, we need to calculate the utility if she purchases an insurance with an actuarially fair premium of $250: The utility for this situation would be: \(U(9750)=\ln{9750}\), because she will spend \(10,000 - 250 = 9,750\) regardless of whether she loses $1000 or not (thanks to the insurance). The expected utility of this situation is just the utility with insurance, since there is no uncertainty anymore.
03

Comparing Expected Utilities

Now we need to see if her expected utility is higher with the insurance than without: Expected Utility (without insurance) = \(0.25 \cdot \ln{9000} + 0.75 \cdot \ln{10000}\) Expected Utility (with insurance) = \(\ln{9750}\) Let's compare them and see if purchasing insurance is beneficial for Ms. Fogg: \(0.25 \cdot \ln{9000} + 0.75 \cdot \ln{10000} < \ln{9750}\) Comparing with a calculator, we can determine if this inequality holds to see if purchasing insurance is beneficial.
04

Maximum Amount for Insurance

To find the maximum amount Ms. Fogg would be willing to pay for the insurance, we need to find the price that would make her indifferent between purchasing or not purchasing it. Let "\(x\)" be the maximum amount Ms. Fogg is willing to pay for insurance. The expected utility without insurance should be equal to the expected utility with insurance at this cost: \(0.25 \cdot \ln{9000} + 0.75 \cdot \ln{10000} = \ln{(10000-x)}\) Now, we need to solve for \(x\): \(x = 10000 - \exp{\left(0.25 \cdot \ln{9000} + 0.75 \cdot \ln{10000}\right)}\) Calculating this expression, we find the maximum amount Ms. Fogg would be willing to pay for the insurance.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Utility Function
Understanding the utility function is like unlocking the secret to a consumer's satisfaction. It's a mathematical tool that economists use to represent a consumer's preference for certain goods or experiences. Think of it as a personal happiness meter, where higher utility means more satisfaction.

For example, in our exercise with Ms. Fogg, her enjoyment of the trip is quantified using the utility function \(U(Y)=\text{ln}Y\). This particular form, a natural logarithm function, is commonly used because it captures the concept of diminishing marginal utility; the idea that each additional dollar spent brings a smaller increase in satisfaction than the last. Ms. Fogg's dilemma with the potential loss of money and decision on buying insurance is assessed through the lens of expected utility, showcasing the interplay between financial decisions and their impact on contentment.
Risk and Insurance in Microeconomics
Risk is an inevitable part of life, and microeconomics doesn't ignore this. It dives into how consumers deal with risk, like the potential of losing money, and how they can use tools such as insurance to manage it.

In our Ms. Fogg scenario, the risk is losing $1000 on her trip. Economists calculate the 'expected utility' to gauge how unpleasant this scenario could be for her. When Ms. Fogg considers purchasing insurance at an actuarially fair premium (a fancy way of saying the insurance cost equals the expected loss), she's acting like a textbook example of risk aversion – preferring to avoid uncertainty even at a small cost. By buying the insurance, Ms. Fogg locks in a known utility, eliminating the gamble and finding peace of mind.
Consumer Choice and Preference
At the crossroads of desires and decisions lie consumer choice and preference. It's all about what people prefer and how they choose among various options considering their limited resources. Consumers face multiple options and must decide which gives them the most bang for their buck, or in economic jargon, 'maximizes their utility.'

Relating back to our globetrotting Ms. Fogg, her preferences are laid out by her utility function. She can opt for buying insurance or risk losing part of her travel fund. The consumer's decision-making process, as reflected in the exercise, demonstrates the delicate balance between risk, cost, and the pursuit of happiness. By determining the maximum amount she's willing to pay for insurance, Ms. Fogg's choices depict a real-world application of microeconomic principles.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

A farmer's tomato crop is wilting, and he must decide whether to water it. If he waters the tomatoes, or if it rains, the crop will yield \(\$ 1,000\) in profits; but if the tomatoes get no water, they will yield only \(\$ 500 .\) Operation of the farmer's irrigation system costs \(\$ 100 .\) The farmer seeks to maximize expected profits from tomato sales. a. If the farmer believes there is a 50 percent chance of rain, should he water? b. What is the maximum amount the farmer would pay to get information from an itiner ant weather forecaster who can predict rain with 100 percent accuracy? c. How would your answer to part (b) change if the forecaster were only 75 percent accurate?

Investment in risky assets can be examined in the state-preference framework by assuming that \(W^{*}\) dollars invested in an asset with a certain return, \(r,\) will yield \(\mathrm{W}^{*}(\mathrm{l}+r)\) in both states of the world, whereas investment in a risky asset will yield \(\mathrm{W}^{*}\left(1+r_{g}\right)\) in good times and \(\left.\mathrm{W}^{*}\left(\mathrm{l}+r_{b}\right) \text { in bad times (where } r_{g}>r>r_{b}\right)\) a. Graph the outcomes from the two investments. b. Show how a "mxied portfolio" containing both risk-free and risky assets could be illustrated in your graph. How would you show the fraction of wealth invested in the risky asset? c. Show how individuals' attitudes toward risk will determine the mix of risk- free and risky assets they will hold. In what case would a person hold no risky assets? d. If an individual's utility takes the constant relative risk aversion form (Equation 8.62 ), ex plain why this person will not change the fraction of risky asset held as his or her wealth increases.

Show that if an individual's utility-of-wealth function is convex (rather than concave, as shown in Figure 8.1 ), he or she will prefer fair gambles to income certainty and may even be willing to accept somewhat unfair gambles. Do you believe this sort of risk-taking behavior is common? What factors might tend to limit its occurrence?

Blue-eyed people are more likely to lose their expensive watches than are brown-eyed people. Specifically, there is an 80 percent probability that a blue-eyed individual will lose a \(\$ 1,000\) watch during a year, but only a 20 percent probability that a brown-eyed person will. Blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally represented in the population. a. If an insurance company assumes blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally likely to buy watch-loss insurance, what will the actuarially fair insurance premium be? b. If blue-eyed and brown-eyed people have logarithmic utility-of-wealth functions and cur rent wealths of \(\$ 10,000\) each, will these individuals buy watch insurance at the premium calculated in part (a)? c. Given your results from part (b), will the insurance premiums be correctly computed? What should the premium be? What will the utility for each type of person be? d. Suppose that an insurance company charged different premiums for blue-eyed and brown-eyed people. How would these individuals' maximum utilities compare to those computed in parts (b) and (c)? (This problem is an example of adverse selection in insurance.)

In some cases individuals may care about the date at which the uncertainty they face is resolved. Suppose, for example, that an individual knows that his or her consumption will be 10 units today \((Q)\) but that tomorrow's consumption \(\left(\mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\) will be either 10 or \(2.5,\) depending on whether a coin comes up heads or tails. Suppose also that the individual's utility function has the simple Cobb-Douglas form \\[U\left(Q, C_{2}\right)=V^{\wedge} Q.\\] a. If an individual cares only about the expected value of utility, will it matter whether the coin is flipped just before day 1 or just before day \(2 ?\) Explain. More generally, suppose that the individual's expected utility depends on the timing of the coin flip. Specifically, assume that \\[\text { expected utility }=\mathbf{f}^{\wedge}\left[\left(\mathrm{fi}\left\\{17\left(\mathrm{C}, \mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\right\\}\right) \text { ) } \text { ? } |\right.\\] where \(E_{x}\) represents expectations taken at the start of day \(1, E_{2}\) represents expectations at the start of day \(2,\) and \(a\) represents a parameter that indicates timing preferences. Show that if \(a=1,\) the individual is indifferent about when the coin is flipped. Show that if \(a=2,\) the individual will prefer early resolution of the uncertainty - that is, flipping the coin at the start of day 1 Show that if \(a=.5,\) the individual will prefer later resolution of the uncertainty (flipping at the start of day 2 ). Explain your results intuitively and indicate their relevance for information theory. (Note: This problem is an illustration of "resolution seeking" and "resolution-averse" behavior. See D. M. Kreps and E. L. Porteus, "Temporal Resolution of Uncertainty and Dynamic Choice Theory," Econometrica [January \(1978]: 185-200\).

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free