Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Blue-eyed people are more likely to lose their expensive watches than are brown-eyed people. Specifically, there is an 80 percent probability that a blue-eyed individual will lose a \(\$ 1,000\) watch during a year, but only a 20 percent probability that a brown-eyed person will. Blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally represented in the population. a. If an insurance company assumes blue-eyed and brown-eyed people are equally likely to buy watch-loss insurance, what will the actuarially fair insurance premium be? b. If blue-eyed and brown-eyed people have logarithmic utility-of-wealth functions and cur rent wealths of \(\$ 10,000\) each, will these individuals buy watch insurance at the premium calculated in part (a)? c. Given your results from part (b), will the insurance premiums be correctly computed? What should the premium be? What will the utility for each type of person be? d. Suppose that an insurance company charged different premiums for blue-eyed and brown-eyed people. How would these individuals' maximum utilities compare to those computed in parts (b) and (c)? (This problem is an example of adverse selection in insurance.)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: If the insurance company charged different premiums for blue-eyed and brown-eyed people, blue-eyed individuals would pay a premium of $800, and brown-eyed individuals would pay a premium of $200. In this scenario, both blue-eyed and brown-eyed individuals would buy insurance at their respective premiums, as their expected utility is higher with insurance.

Step by step solution

01

Calculate Expected Losses

To calculate the actuarially fair insurance premium, we need to find the expected losses for both types of people. For blue-eyed people: E(LossB) = 0.80 * \$1,000 = \$800 For brown-eyed people: E(LossBR) = 0.20 * \$1,000 = \$200 Since the population has equal representation of both types, the combined expected loss is the average: E(Loss) = (\$800 + \$200) / 2 = \$500 Thus, the actuarially fair insurance premium should be $500. #b. Buying insurance at the premium calculated in part (a)#
02

Calculate Utility Without Insurance

Both blue-eyed and brown-eyed individuals have logarithmic utility functions and a current wealth of \$10,000. We first calculate their expected utility without insurance: Blue-eyed individuals: • With loss, 80% chance: U(W - Loss) = ln(\$9,000) • Without loss, 20% chance: U(W) = ln(\$10,000) Brown-eyed individuals: • With loss, 20% chance: U(W - Loss) = ln(\$9,000) • Without loss, 80% chance: U(W) = ln(\$10,000)
03

Calculate Utility With Insurance

Calculate the expected utility for both types with actuarially fair insurance premium calculated in part(a): Blue-eyed individuals: • With loss, 80% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,500) • Without loss, 20% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,500) Brown-eyed individuals: • With loss, 20% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,500) • Without loss, 80% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,500) Considering the calculated utilities, both blue-eyed and brown-eyed individuals would prefer buying insurance at the actuarially fair premium of \$500, as their expected utility is higher with insurance. #c. Correct premium and utilities#
04

Evaluate the Correctness of Premiums

As we saw, both types of individuals would buy insurance at the premium calculated based on their expected losses. But since blue-eyed people have a higher risk of losing the watch, and they are more likely to buy insurance, the calculated premium will be underestimated.
05

Calculate New Premium and Utilities

To find the correct premium, we can find the weighted average loss considering the number of insured individuals from each group. For simplicity, let's assume all blue-eyed individuals buy insurance, and none of the brown-eyed individuals do. The new premium would then be: Premium = E(LossB) = \$800 Now recalculate utilities for blue-eyed individuals with this premium: • With loss, 80% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,200) • Without loss, 20% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,200) For blue-eyed individuals, the new utility is higher without insurance. Thus, they would not buy insurance at the correct premium of \$800. #d. Charging different premiums and utilities#
06

Calculate Utilities with Different Premiums

If the insurance company charged different premiums for blue-eyed and brown-eyed people, the premiums would be equal to their expected losses. Blue-eyed individuals would have a premium of \$800, and brown-eyed individuals would have a premium of \$200. In this case, the expected utility with insurance for both types would be the same: Blue-eyed individuals: • With loss, 80% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,200) • Without loss, 20% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,200) Brown-eyed individuals: • With loss, 20% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,800) • Without loss, 80% chance: U(W - Premium) = ln(\$9,800) Comparing these utilities to those without insurance, both blue-eyed and brown-eyed individuals would buy insurance at their respective premiums in this scenario.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Actuarially Fair Premium
The concept of an actuarially fair premium is crucial when it comes to insurance. It represents the average expected loss that an insured person may face over time. In simple terms, it is the premium amount that would perfectly balance the insurance company's expenses and its payouts to policyholders.
This idea of fairness ensures that the insurance company does not make a profit or a loss on average. It is calculated based on the probability of a loss occurring and the amount of the loss.
For example, in the exercise provided, blue-eyed individuals have an 80% chance of losing a $1,000 watch, leading to an expected loss of $800. Brown-eyed individuals have a 20% chance, which results in an expected loss of $200. With half of the population in each category, the combined actuarially fair premium would be $500. This approach integrates the risk for both groups, equating to the average expected loss across the entire insured population.
Expected Utility
Expected utility is a concept used in economics to measure the desirability of uncertain outcomes. It is the sum of utilities across all possible outcomes, weighted by their probability.
In this context, it helps individuals decide whether or not they should purchase insurance. Utility reflects satisfaction or happiness an individual gets from a particular outcome.
People are generally risk-averse, meaning they prefer a certain outcome over taking a gamble. Thus, they weigh their decision by considering potential losses and gains.
In our example, the expected utility without insurance for a blue-eyed individual considers both the chance of losing the watch and not losing it, calculated using a logarithmic utility function. By purchasing insurance, individuals can achieve a smoother and more predictable utility, potentially leading to better financial security and peace of mind.
Logarithmic Utility
Logarithmic utility is a specific type of utility function often used in economic models. It's formulated as the natural logarithm of wealth, expressed as \( U(W) = \ln(W) \).
This function captures risk aversion — individuals value incremental increases in wealth less as they become wealthier, a property known as diminishing marginal utility.
In our watch insurance scenario, both blue-eyed and brown-eyed individuals have logarithmic utility functions.
Their decision to purchase insurance at a given premium can be understood by comparing the expected utility of different choices. For instance, the utility with insurance is calculated by considering the reduction in wealth by the premium but eliminates the large uncertain loss.
Logarithmic utility functions model real-world attitudes toward risk by making clear why individuals may buy insurance to protect against significant financial losses.
Insurance Premium Computation
Insurance premium computation involves calculating the premium cost so that it reflects the risk each insured individual poses.
Initially determined using expected losses, it ensures that premiums are fair based on expected value calculations. In our example, it would initially appear that both groups pay $500. However, this does not account for adverse selection, where higher-risk individuals are more likely to purchase coverage.
Ultimately, correctly computed premiums might differ between individuals of differing risk levels to avoid adverse selection. In this scenario, blue-eyed people should face higher premiums of $800, while brown-eyed individuals would pay $200, proportional to their expected losses.
Separating premiums improves fairness and ensures that each individual pays in accordance with their actual risk, maintaining the balance in the insurance market. It is a delicate balance that requires understanding risk and economic behavior to be done effectively.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose Molly Jock wishes to purchase a high-definition television to watch the Olympic Greco-Roman wrestling competition. Her current income is \(\$ 20,000,\) and she knows where she can buy the television she wants for \(\$ 2,000\). She has heard the rumor that the same set can be bought at Crazy Eddie's (recently out of bankruptcy) for \(\$ 1,700,\) but is unsure if the rumor is true. Suppose this individual's utility is given by \\[\text { utility }=\ln (Y).\\] where Fis her income after buying the television. a. What is Molly's utility if she buys from the location she knows? b. What is Molly's utility if Crazy Eddie's really does offer the lower price? c. Suppose Molly believes there is a \(50-50\) chance that Crazy Eddie does offer the lowerpriced television, but it will cost her \(\$ 100\) to drive to the discount store to find out for sure (the store is far away and has had its phone disconnected). Is it worth it to her to invest the money in the trip?

Suppose there is a \(50-50\) chance that a risk-averse individual with a current wealth of \(\$ 20,000\) will contact a debilitating disease and suffer a loss of \(\$ 10,000\) a. Calculate the cost of actuarially fair insurance in this situation and use a utility-of-wealth graph (such as shown in Figure 8.1 ) to show that the individual will prefer fair insurance against this loss to accepting the gamble uninsured. b. Suppose two types of insurance policies were available: (1) A fair policy covering the complete loss. (2) A fair policy covering only half of any loss incurred. Calculate the cost of the second type of policy and show that the individual will generally regard it as inferior to the first.

A farmer believes there is a \(50-50\) chance that the next growing season will be abnormally rainy. His expected utility function has the form \\[ \begin{array}{c} \mathbf{1} \\ \text { expected utility }=-\boldsymbol{I} \boldsymbol{n} \boldsymbol{Y}_{N R}+-\boldsymbol{I} \boldsymbol{n} \boldsymbol{Y}_{R} \end{array} \\] where \(Y_{N R}\) and \(Y_{R}\) represent the farmer's income in the states of "normal rain" and "rainy," respectively. a. Suppose the farmer must choose between two crops that promise the following income prospects: $$\begin{array}{lcr} \text { Crop } & Y_{H} & Y_{R} \\ \hline \text { Wheat } & \$ 28,000 & \$ 10,000 \\ \text { Corn } & 19,000 & 15,000 \end{array}$$ Which of the crops will he plant? b. Suppose the farmer can plant half his field with each crop. Would he choose to do so? Explain your result. c. What mix of wheat and corn would provide maximum expected utility to this farmer? d. Would wheat crop insurance, available to farmers who grow only wheat, which costs \(\$ 4000\) and pays off \(\$ 8000\) in the event of a rainy growing season, cause this farmer to change what he plants?

In some cases individuals may care about the date at which the uncertainty they face is resolved. Suppose, for example, that an individual knows that his or her consumption will be 10 units today \((Q)\) but that tomorrow's consumption \(\left(\mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\) will be either 10 or \(2.5,\) depending on whether a coin comes up heads or tails. Suppose also that the individual's utility function has the simple Cobb-Douglas form \\[U\left(Q, C_{2}\right)=V^{\wedge} Q.\\] a. If an individual cares only about the expected value of utility, will it matter whether the coin is flipped just before day 1 or just before day \(2 ?\) Explain. More generally, suppose that the individual's expected utility depends on the timing of the coin flip. Specifically, assume that \\[\text { expected utility }=\mathbf{f}^{\wedge}\left[\left(\mathrm{fi}\left\\{17\left(\mathrm{C}, \mathrm{C}_{2}\right)\right\\}\right) \text { ) } \text { ? } |\right.\\] where \(E_{x}\) represents expectations taken at the start of day \(1, E_{2}\) represents expectations at the start of day \(2,\) and \(a\) represents a parameter that indicates timing preferences. Show that if \(a=1,\) the individual is indifferent about when the coin is flipped. Show that if \(a=2,\) the individual will prefer early resolution of the uncertainty - that is, flipping the coin at the start of day 1 Show that if \(a=.5,\) the individual will prefer later resolution of the uncertainty (flipping at the start of day 2 ). Explain your results intuitively and indicate their relevance for information theory. (Note: This problem is an illustration of "resolution seeking" and "resolution-averse" behavior. See D. M. Kreps and E. L. Porteus, "Temporal Resolution of Uncertainty and Dynamic Choice Theory," Econometrica [January \(1978]: 185-200\).

An individual purchases a dozen eggs and must take them home. Although making trips home is costless, there is a 50 percent chance that all of the eggs carried on any one trip will be broken during the trip. The individual considers two strategies: Strategy 1: Take all 12 eggs in one trip. Strategy 2: Take two trips with 6 in each trip. a. List the possible outcomes of each strategy and the probabilities of these outcomes. Show that on the average, 6 eggs will remain unbroken after the trip home under either strategy. b. Develop a graph to show the utility obtainable under each strategy. Which strategy will be preferable? c. Could utility be improved further by taking more than two trips? How would this possi bility be affected if additional trips were costly?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free