Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose the total cost function for a firm is given by \\[ T C-q w^{23} v^{13} \\] a. Use Shephard's lemma (footnote 8 ) to compute the constant output demand functions for inputs \(L\) and \(K\) b. Use your results from part (a) to calculate the underlying production function for \(q\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Question: Using Shephard's lemma and given the total cost function \(TC = q w^{23} v^{13}\), find the constant output demand functions for inputs \(L\) and \(K\), and calculate the underlying production function for output \(q\). Answer: The constant output demand functions for inputs \(L\) and \(K\) are: \(L(w,v,q) = 23w^{22} v^{13}\) \(K(w,v,q) = w^{23} 13v^{12}\) The underlying production function for output \(q\) is: \(q(L,K) = \frac{13L}{23} + \frac{23K}{13}\)

Step by step solution

01

Take Partial Derivatives of Total Cost Function

First, we have to find the partial derivatives of the total cost function with respect to \(w\) and \(v\). Given the total cost function, \\[ TC = q w^{23} v^{13} \\], let's take the partial derivatives: For the partial derivative with respect to \(w\): \\[ \frac{\partial TC}{\partial w} = q \cdot 23w^{22} v^{13} \\] For the partial derivative with respect to \(v\): \\[ \frac{\partial TC}{\partial v} = q \cdot w^{23} 13v^{12} \\]
02

Compute Constant Output Demand Functions for Inputs \(L\) and \(K\)

According to Shephard's lemma, the partial derivatives with respect to input prices represent the constant output demand functions for the corresponding inputs. Therefore, the constant output demand functions for inputs \(L\) and \(K\) are given by: For input \(L\) (input prices correspond to \(w\)): \\[ L(w,v,q) = 23w^{22} v^{13} \\] For input \(K\) (input prices correspond to \(v\)): \\[ K(w,v,q) = w^{23} 13v^{12} \\]
03

Calculate the Underlying Production Function for \(q\)

Now that we have the constant output demand functions for inputs \(L\) and \(K\), we can compute the underlying production function for \(q\). To do this, set \(L(w,v,q)\) and \(K(w,v,q)\) equal to \(L\) and \(K\), respectively: For input \(L\): \\[ L = 23w^{22} v^{13} \\] For input \(K\): \\[ K = w^{23} 13v^{12} \\] Now, eliminate \(w\) and \(v\) from the above equations to get the production function. Divide the first equation by the second equation to get: \\[ \frac{L}{K} = \frac{23}{13} \] Now, solve for \(q\): \\[ q = \frac{13L}{23} + \frac{23K}{13} \\] The underlying production function for output \(q\) is given by: \\[ q(L,K) = \frac{13L}{23} + \frac{23K}{13} \\]

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Total Cost Function
Understanding the total cost function is crucial for economics students as it represents the expenses a firm incurs from all sources to produce a given level of output. It encapsulates various costs like fixed costs, variable costs, and at times, semi-variable costs. Specifically, the total cost function in the form of \( TC = q w^{23} v^{13} \) indicates an algebraic relationship between the total cost, the quantity produced \( q \), and the prices of inputs denoted by \( w \) and \( v \).

Shephard's lemma plays a significant role here. It tells us that partial derivatives of the total cost function with respect to input prices yield the demand functions for those inputs, assuming output level stays constant. These derivatives reflect how sensitive the quantity of an input is with respect to its price, holding the output fixed. By understanding this relationship, businesses can optimize their input use to minimize costs or adjust to price changes in the input markets.
Constant Output Demand Functions
The constant output demand functions are a direct application of Shephard's lemma. They are derived from the total cost function assuming the output level remains unchanged. In the context of our exercise, the demand functions for inputs \( L \) and \( K \) denote the quantity of labor and capital required to produce a certain quantity of output at constant prices.

More formally, these functions are expressed as \( L(w,v,q) \) and \( K(w,v,q) \), representing the amount of labor and capital demanded for any combination of their respective prices \( w \) and \( v \), and the level of output \( q \). These functions allow firms to make predictions about their required inputs and help economists understand the firm's production behavior under constant output conditions. They are a fundamental concept in understanding how production inputs are allocated in the short run, where output levels are often inflexible.
Production Function
The production function represents the relationship between the quantities of inputs used and the level of output achieved. It is expressed in the form \( q(L,K) \), signifying that the output \( q \) is a function of labor \( L \) and capital \( K \). In our exercise, we have derived the production function from the constant output demand functions and Shephard's lemma. By equating the constant demand functions for labor and capital to \( L \) and \( K \) and then eliminating \( w \) and \( v \), we obtained the relationship between labor and capital which can be used to calculate output.

The production function is central to the study of producer's behavior because it embodies the technological constraints facing the firm. It indicates the highest level of output attainable with a given set of inputs, and it's essential for understanding economies of scale, marginal rates of technical substitution, and the law of diminishing returns - all key concepts in microeconomic production theory.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that a firm produces two different outputs, the quantities of which are represented by \(q^{\wedge}\) and \(q_{2},\) In general, the firm's total costs can be represented by \(T C\left\\{q_{n} q_{2}\right)\) This function \right. exhibits economies of scope if \(T C\left(q_{w} 0\right)+T C\left(0, q_{2}\right)>T C\left(q_{w} q_{2}\right)\) for all output levels of either good. a. Explain in words why this mathematical formulation implies that costs will be lower in this multiproduct firm than in two single-product firms producing each good separately. b. If the two outputs are actually the same good, we can define total output as \(q=<,+q_{2}\) Suppose that in this case average cost \((=T C / q)\) falls as \(q\) increases. Show that this firm also enjoys economies of scope under the definition provided here.

Suppose, as in Problem \(12.6,\) a firm produces hockey sticks with a production function of \(q=2 \mathrm{V} K L\). Capital stock is fixed at \(K\) in the short run. a. Calculate the firm's total costs as a function of \(q, w, v,\) and \(K\) b. Given \(q, w,\) and \(v,\) how should the capital stock be chosen to minimize total cost? c. Use your results from part (b) to calculate the long-run total cost of hockey stick production d. For \(w-\$ 4, v-\$ 1,\) graph the long-run total cost curve for hockey stick production. Show that this is an envelope for the short-run curves computed in part (a) by examin ing values of \(K\) of \(100,200,\) and 400

Suppose that a firm's fixed proportion production function is given by \\[ q=\min (5 K, 10 \mathrm{L}) \\] and that the rental rates for capital and labor are given by \(v=1, w-3\) a. Calculate the firm's long-run total, average, and marginal cost curves. b. Suppose that Xis fixed at 10 in the short run. Calculate the firm's short- run total, aver age, and marginal cost curves, What is the marginal cost of the 10 th unit? The 50 th unit? The 100 th unit?

Professor Smith and Professor Jones are going to produce a new introductory textbook. As true scientists, they have laid out the production function for the book as \\[ q=S^{1 / 2} J^{1 / 2} \\] where \(q=\) the number of pages in the finished book, \(S=\) the number of working hours spent by Smith, and \(J=\) the number of hours spent working by Jones. Smith values his labor as \(\$ 3\) per working hour. He has spent 900 hours preparing the first draft. Jones, whose labor is valued at \(\$ 12\) per working hour, will revise Smith's draft to complete the book. a. How many hours will Jones have to spend to produce a finished book of 150 pages? Of 300 pages? Of 450 pages? b. What is the marginal cost of the 150 th page of the finished book? Of the 300 th page? Of the 450 th page?12.1 In a famous article [J. Viner, "Cost Curves and Supply Curves," Zeilschríl fur Nationalokonomie \(3 \text { (September } 1931 \text { ): } 23-46]\), Viner criticized his draftsman who could not draw a family of \(S A T C\) curves whose points of tangency with the U-shaped \(A C\) curve were also the minimum points on each \(S A T C\) curve. The draftsman protested that such a drawing was impossible to construct. Whom would you support in this debate?

Suppose the total cost function for a firm is given by \\[ T C=(.5 v+W v w+.5 w) q \\] a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the constant output demand function for each in put, ifand \(L\) b. Use the results from part (a) to compute the underlying production function for \(q\) c. You can check the result by using results from Extension \(\mathrm{E} 12.2\) to show that the CES cost function with \(a-(3-.5\) generates this total cost function.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free