Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The general form for the expenditure function of the almost ideal demand system (AIDS) is given by \\[ \begin{aligned} \ln E\left(p_{1}, \ldots, p_{n}, U\right)=& a_{0}+\sum_{i=1}^{n} \alpha_{i} \ln p_{i}+\frac{1}{2} \sum_{i=1}^{n} \sum_{j=1}^{n} \gamma_{i j} \ln p_{i} \ln p_{j} \\ &+U \beta_{0} \prod_{i=1}^{k} p_{k}^{\beta_{i}} \end{aligned} \\] For analytical ease, assume that the following restrictions apply: \\[ \gamma_{i j}=\gamma_{j i}, \quad \sum_{i=1}^{n} \alpha_{i}=1, \quad \text { and } \quad \sum_{j=1}^{n} \gamma_{i j}=\sum_{k=1}^{n} \beta_{k}=0 \\] a. Derive the AIDS functional form for a two-goods case. b. Given the previous restrictions, show that this expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices. This, along with the fact that this function resembles closely the actual data, makes it an "ideal" function. c. Using the fact that \(s_{x}=\frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_{x}}\) (see Problem 5.8 ), calculate the income share of each of the two goods.

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary, we derived the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) functional form for a two-goods case, showed that the expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices, and calculated the income share of each of the two goods using the given formula. The income share of good 1, \(s_1\), is given by \(\alpha_1 + \gamma_{11} \ln p_1 + \gamma_{12} \ln p_2\), whereas the income share of good 2, \(s_2\), is given by \(\alpha_2 + \gamma_{21} \ln p_1 + \gamma_{22} \ln p_2\).

Step by step solution

01

Simplify the general formula for two-goods case

Substitute n=2 (two-goods) in the given general formula and write down the simplified equation: \\[ \begin{aligned} \ln E\left(p_1, p_2, U\right) &= a_0 + \alpha_1 \ln p_1 + \alpha_2 \ln p_2 + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{11} (\ln p_1)^2 + \gamma_{12} \ln p_1 \ln p_2 + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{22} (\ln p_2)^2 \\ &+ U \beta_0 p_1^{\beta_1} p_2^{\beta_2} \end{aligned} \\] #b. Show that the expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices#
02

Apply homogeneity condition

To show the expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices, we need to replace \(p_i\) with \(\lambda p_i\) and show that the resulting function is \(\ln E(\lambda p_1, \lambda p_2, U) = \ln E(p_1, p_2, U) + \ln \lambda\). Make this substitution and simplify the equation: \\[ \begin{aligned} \ln E\left(\lambda p_1, \lambda p_2, U\right) &= a_0 + \alpha_1 \ln (\lambda p_1) + \alpha_2 \ln (\lambda p_2) + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{11} (\ln (\lambda p_1))^2 + \gamma_{12} \ln (\lambda p_1) \ln (\lambda p_2) \\ &+ \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{22} (\ln (\lambda p_2))^2 + U \beta_0 (\lambda p_1)^{\beta_1} (\lambda p_2)^{\beta_2} \\ &= a_0 + \alpha_1 (\ln \lambda + \ln p_1) + \alpha_2 (\ln \lambda + \ln p_2) + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{11} (\ln \lambda + \ln p_1)^2 \\ &+ \gamma_{12} (\ln \lambda + \ln p_1) (\ln \lambda + \ln p_2) + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{22} (\ln \lambda + \ln p_2)^2 \\ &+ U \beta_0 (\lambda^{\beta_1} p_1^{\beta_1})(\lambda^{\beta_2} p_2^{\beta_2}) \end{aligned} \\]
03

Simplify the equation and apply given restrictions

Now, simplify the above equation while remembering to apply the given restrictions: \\[ \begin{aligned} \ln E\left(\lambda p_1, \lambda p_2, U\right) - \ln \lambda &= a_0 + (\alpha_1 + \alpha_2) \ln \lambda + \alpha_1 \ln p_1 + \alpha_2 \ln p_2 + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{11} (\ln p_1)^2 \\ &+ \gamma_{12} \ln p_1 \ln p_2 + \frac{1}{2} \gamma_{22} (\ln p_2)^2 + \ln \lambda (\beta_1 + \beta_2) + U \beta_0 p_1^{\beta_1} p_2^{\beta_2} \\ &= \ln E( p_1, p_2, U) \end{aligned} \\] Thus, our expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices. #c. Calculate the income share of each of the two goods#
04

Apply the given formula for income share and find the derivatives

In order to find the income share of each good, apply the given formula \(s_x = \frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_x}\) on the two-goods AIDS expenditure function: \\[ \begin{aligned} s_1 &= \frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_1} = \alpha_1 + \gamma_{11} \ln p_1 + \gamma_{12} \ln p_2 \\ s_2 &= \frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_2} = \alpha_2 + \gamma_{21} \ln p_1 + \gamma_{22} \ln p_2 \end{aligned} \\] Now we have the income share of both goods 1 and 2, \(s_1\) and \(s_2\), using the given formula.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Expenditure Function in the Almost Ideal Demand System
The expenditure function is a powerful concept in economics that tells us how much a consumer needs to spend to reach a certain utility level, given the prices of goods. In the context of the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), it relates utility to the prices of goods and income levels in a flexible form that can be adjusted for various numbers of goods.

The AIDS expenditure function provided in the exercise demonstrates the relationship between two goods, their prices, and the utility level of the consumer. It's represented in a log-linear form which is mathematically convenient and provides insights into consumer behavior. When you are calculating the AIDS functional form for a two-goods case, you're essentially simplifying the general formula to work specifically with just two goods, by plugging in n=2 into the general formula.

Understanding the AIDS expenditure function helps in analyzing consumer budgeting and spending patterns, which are vital for studying market dynamics and formulating economic policies.
Homogeneity of Degree 1 of the Expenditure Function
Homogeneity of degree 1 is a term that refers to the characteristic of a function to maintain its proportional relationship when all its arguments are scaled by a constant factor. In simpler terms, if you double the prices of all goods, you'd expect to need to double your budget to maintain the same level of utility.

In the context of the AIDS expenditure function, proving that it's homogeneous of degree 1 involves showing that if you multiply all prices by a constant, the new level of expenditure would just be that constant multiplied by the original level of expenditure. This property is important because it ensures that the function maintains consistency with economic theory, which assumes that only relative prices matter to consumers, not the absolute levels of price.

The substitution step demonstrated in the exercise is key for proving this property. Applying the restrictions, such as the sum of the parameters being equal to 0, simplifies the equation and completes the proof. This characteristic reinforces the practicality of the AIDS model and forms the basis for its widespread use in economic analyses.
Calculating the Income Share for Goods
Income share in economics represents the proportion of total income that is spent on a particular good. When looking at two goods specifically, the income share tells us how a consumer's budget is split between those two products. It's a fundamental concept that reflects consumers' preferences and the importance of each good within their consumption pattern.

In the exercise solution, the income share of each of the two goods is determined by using partial derivatives of the log of the expenditure function with respect to the log of each good's price. This calculation is grounded in the idea that small changes in the prices of goods will impact the overall expenditure in varying degrees, corresponding to each good's share of the budget.

By applying the formula given in the exercise and using the specified functional form, you can solve for the income shares of both goods. These shares are vital for understanding market demands as well as for making pricing decisions and economic forecasting. The AIDS model offers a nuanced approach to assessing how shifts in prices influence consumer spending patterns.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Show that the share of income spent on a good \(x\) is \(s_{x}=\frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_{x}},\) where \(E\) is total expenditure

The three aggregation relationships presented in this chapter can be generalized to any number of goods. This problem asks you to do so. We assume that there are \(n\) goods and that the share of income devoted to good \(i\) is denoted by \(s_{i} .\) We also define the following elasticities: \\[ \begin{array}{l} e_{i, I}=\frac{\partial x_{i}}{\partial I} \cdot \frac{I}{x_{i}} \\ e_{i, j}=\frac{\partial x_{i}}{\partial p_{j}} \cdot \frac{p_{j}}{x_{i}} \end{array} \\] Use this notation to show: a. Homogeneity: \(\sum_{j=1}^{n} e_{i, j}+e_{i, l}=0\) b. Engel aggregation: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} s_{i} e_{i, I}=1\) c. Cournot aggregation: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} s_{i} e_{i, j}=-s_{j}\)

Over a 3 -year period, an individual exhibits the following consumption behavior: $$\begin{array}{lcccc} & p_{x} & p_{y} & x & y \\ \hline \text {Year 1} & 3 & 3 & 7 & 4 \\ \text {Year 2} & 4 & 2 & 6 & 6 \\ \text {Year 3} & 5 & 1 & 7 & 3 \\ \hline \end{array}$$ Is this behavior consistent with the principles of revealed preference theory?

In the Extensions to Chapter 4 we showed that most empirical work in demand theory focuses on income shares. For any good \(x,\) the income share is defined as \(s_{x}=p_{x} x / I .\) In this problem we show that most demand elasticities can be derived from corresponding share elasticities. a. Show that the elasticity of a good's budget share with respect to income \(\left(e_{s_{n} I}=\partial s_{x} / \partial I \cdot I / s_{x}\right)\) is equal to \(e_{x, l}-1 .\) Interpret this conclusion with a few numerical examples. b. Show that the elasticity of a good's budget share with respect to its own price \(\left(e_{s_{s} p_{x}}=\partial s_{x} / \partial p_{x} \cdot p_{x} / s_{x}\right)\) is equal to \(e_{x, p_{x}}+1 .\) Again, interpret this finding with a few numerical examples. c. Use your results from part (b) to show that the "expenditure elasticity" of good \(x\) with respect to its own price \(\left[e_{p_{x} \cdot x, p_{x}}=\partial\left(p_{x} \cdot x\right) / \partial p_{x} \cdot 1 / x\right]\) is also equal to \(e_{x, p_{x}}+1\) d. Show that the elasticity of a good's budget share with respect to a change in the price of some other good \(\left(e_{s_{s} p_{y}}=\partial s_{x} / \partial p_{y} \cdot p_{y} / s_{x}\right)\) is equal to \(e_{x, p}\) e. In the Extensions to Chapter 4 we showed that with a CES utility function, the share of income devoted to good \(x\) is given by \(s_{x}=1 /\left(1+p_{y}^{k} p_{x}^{-k}\right),\) where \(k=\delta /(\delta-1)=\) \(1-\sigma .\) Use this share equation to prove Equation 5.56 \(e_{x^{\prime}, p_{x}}=-\left(1-s_{x}\right) \sigma\)

Thirsty Ed drinks only pure spring water, but he can purchase it in two different-sized containers: 0.75 liter and 2 liter. Because the water itself is identical, he regards these two "goods" as perfect substitutes. a. Assuming Ed's utility depends only on the quantity of water consumed and that the containers themselves yield no utility, express this utility function in terms of quantities of 0.75 -liter containers \((x)\) and 2 -liter containers \((y)\) b. State Ed's demand function for \(x\) in terms of \(p_{x}, p_{y},\) and \(I\) c. Graph the demand curve for \(x\), holding \(I\) and \(p_{y}\) constant. d. How do changes in \(I\) and \(p_{y}\) shift the demand curve for \(x ?\) e. What would the compensated demand curve for \(x\) look like in this situation?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free