Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The analysis of public goods in this chapter exclusively used a model with only two individuals. The results are readily generalized to \(n\) persons-a generalization pursued in this problem. a. With \(n\) persons in an economy, what is the condition for efficient production of a public good? Explain how the characteristics of the public good are reflected in these conditions. b. What is the Nash equilibrium in the provision of this public good to \(n\) persons? Explain why this equilibrium is inefficient. Also explain why the underprovision of this public good is more severe than in the two-person cases studied in the chapter. c. How is the Lindahl solution generalized to \(n\) persons? Is the existence of a Lindahl equilibrium guaranteed in this more complex model?

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: The condition for efficient production of a public good in an economy with n individuals is when the sum of marginal benefits equals the marginal cost of production, i.e., \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} MB_i = MC\). The Nash equilibrium is inefficient in this scenario because individuals do not account for the positive externality their contribution brings to others, leading to underprovision of the public good. As the number of individuals increases, the incentive for each individual to free ride (benefit from the public good without contributing) also increases, causing the public good to be even more underprovided.

Step by step solution

01

Recall the efficient production condition

In a two-person economy, the condition for efficient production of a public good is when the sum of marginal benefits equals the marginal cost of production. In a general economy with \(n\) individuals, the same principle applies.
02

Write the equation for efficient production

Given \(n\) persons, each with their own marginal benefit function of a public good, the condition for efficient production of the public good can be given by: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} MB_i = MC\) where, \(MB_i\) is the marginal benefit for person \(i\), and \(MC\) is the marginal cost of production. This equation reflects the characteristics of the public good because it indicates that the total benefit of producing the public good, aggregated across all individuals, should equate with the cost of producing the good. #b. Nash equilibrium and inefficiency#
03

Define Nash equilibrium for public goods

A Nash equilibrium occurs when each individual's chosen contribution to the public good is a best response to the choices made by the other individuals, and no one has an incentive to change their own decision.
04

Describe inefficiency in the Nash equilibrium

In the Nash equilibrium, each individual does not account for the positive externality their contribution brings to others. This leads to underprovision of the public good, as individuals tend to contribute less than the socially optimal amount.
05

Explain why inefficiency is more severe in the \(n\)-person case

Compared to the two-person case studied in the chapter, underprovision of the public good is more severe in the \(n\)-person case. This is because the collective action problem becomes more prominent with a larger number of individuals. As the number of people increases, the incentive for each individual to free ride (i.e., benefit from the public good without contributing) also increases, causing the public good to be even more underprovided. #c. Generalization of Lindahl solution and existence of Lindahl equilibrium#
06

Generalize Lindahl solution for \(n\) persons

The Lindahl solution for \(n\) persons means each person faces a Lindahl tax, calculating their share of the cost of providing the public good, based on their marginal benefit function. In this case, we solve for the set of individual Lindahl prices (\(p_i\)) and the level of public good (\(G\)) that satisfy the efficiency condition: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} p_i G = C(G)\), where \(C(G)\) represents the total cost of providing the public good. Each person's Lindahl tax rate, \(p_i\), should be set such that their marginal benefit equals their share of the marginal cost: \(MB_i(G)=p_i MC(G)\) for each \(i\), \(i= 1, 2, ... , n\)
07

Discuss the existence of Lindahl equilibrium in the \(n\)-person model

The existence of a Lindahl equilibrium in this more complex model depends on the particular structure of the individuals' preferences and the cost functions. If a stable point can be found where all individuals' marginal benefits equal their share of the marginal costs, and the efficient condition is satisfied, then the Lindahl equilibrium exists. However, there is no guarantee that such an equilibrium can always be found, as the solution may depend on the specific characteristics of the public good, cost functions, and individuals' preferences.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Efficient Production Condition
When discussing public goods, the notion of production efficiency is crucial. In microeconomics, a public good, such as a national defense system or public parks, is non-excludable and non-rivalrous, meaning it is available to all, and one person's consumption does not reduce its availability to others.

To achieve efficiency in the production of a public good—where the resources are utilized in the best possible manner to maximize community satisfaction—economists refer to an essential condition: the sum of each individual’s marginal benefits (\(MB_i\) for individual 'i') from the public good should equal the marginal cost (\(MC\)) of producing that good. This is represented mathematically as \[\sum_{i=1}^{n} MB_i = MC\] for an economy with 'n' individuals. This efficient production condition reflects the collective nature of public goods, as it ensures that the good is produced until the last unit where the total value to the society justifies the production cost.

Understanding this concept is vital when analyzing collective decisions about resource allocation for public goods. It indicates a socially optimum production level, guiding policymakers in public spending.
Nash Equilibrium in Public Goods
The Nash equilibrium is a fundamental concept in game theory, illuminating how individuals behave in strategic situations. When applied to public goods, it uncovers a standard predicament. In a Nash equilibrium for public goods provision, every person chooses the amount to contribute based on the others' contributions, leading to a stable state where no one wishes to change their contribution unilaterally.

However, this scenario presents a flaw: inefficiency. The equilibrium tends to be inefficient because it results in the underprovision of the public good. That's because individuals often ignore the full value their contribution brings to others—the positive externality—and thus contribute less than what would be socially optimal.

The inefficiency escalates as more people join the group (\(n\) persons). This is due to the 'free rider' problem, where individuals have less incentive to contribute, expecting others to bear the cost. This collective interaction aggravates the dilemma, causing a more significant shortfall in the provision of the public good compared to a two-person scenario.
Lindahl Solution for Public Goods
The Lindahl solution offers a theoretically equitable method for financing public goods. It suggests that people should pay for the public good in proportion to the benefit they derive from it. For 'n' individuals, this implies a personalized price or tax for each person, aligning with their marginal benefit from the good.

Under this method, the goal is to find the set of Lindahl prices (\(p_i\) for individual 'i') that fulfill the following two conditions:
  • Every individual's marginal benefit equals their share of the marginal cost (\(MB_i(G) = p_i MC(G)\)).
  • The sum of the individual payments equal the total cost of providing the public good (\[\sum_{i=1}^{n} p_i G = C(G)\]), where \(C(G)\) stands for the total cost.

The Lindahl solution, elegant in theory, faces practical challenges. The existence of a Lindahl equilibrium isn't guaranteed in a more complicated multi-person context, as it hinges on individuals accurately revealing their valuation for the public good, which can be strategically manipulated. Moreover, finding a stable point where everyone's marginal benefits equal their share of the costs can be arduous, given the diversity of preference and cost function complexities in a community.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose a monopoly produces a harmful externality. Use the concept of consumer surplus in a partial equilibrium diagram to analyze whether an optimal tax on the polluter would necessarily be a welfare improvement.

Suppose there are three individuals in society trying to rank three social states \((A, B, \text { and } C) .\) For each of the methods of social choice indicated, develop an example to show how the resulting social ranking of \(A, B,\) and \(C\) will be intransitive (as in the paradox of voting ) or indeterminate. a. Majority rule without vote trading. b. Majority rule with vote trading. c. Point voting where each voter can give \(1,2,\) or 3 points to each alternative and the alternative with the highest point total is selected.

A firm in a perfectly competitive industry has patented a new process for making widgets. The new process lowers the firm's average cost, meaning that this firm alone (although still a price taker) can earn real economic profits in the long run. a. If the market price is \(\$ 20\) per widget and the firm's marginal cost is given by \(M C=0.4 q\), where \(q\) is the daily widget production for the firm, how many widgets will the firm produce? b. Suppose a government study has found that the firm's new process is polluting the air and estimates the social marginal cost of widget production by this firm to be \(S M C=0.5 q .\) If the market price is still \(\$ 20,\) what is the socially optimal level of production for the firm? What should be the rate of a government-imposed excise tax to bring about this optimal level of production? c. Graph your results.

There is considerable legal controversy about product safety. Two extreme positions might be termed caveat emptor (let the buyer beware) and caveat vendor (let the seller beware). Under the former scheme producers would have no responsibility for the safety of their products: Buyers would absorb all losses. Under the latter scheme this liability assignment would be reversed: Firms would be completely responsible under law for losses incurred from unsafe products. Using simple supply and demand analysis, discuss how the assignment of such liability might affect the allocation of resources. Would safer products be produced if firms were strictly liable under law? How do possible information asymmetries affect your results?

Suppose the oil industry in Utopia is perfectly competitive and that all firms draw oil from a single (and practically inexhaustible ) pool. Assume that each competitor believes that it can sell all the oil it can produce at a stable world price of \(\$ 10\) per barrel and that the cost of operating a well for 1 year is \(\$ 1,000\) Total output per year (Q) of the oil field is a function of the number of wells ( \(n\) ) operating in the field. In particular, \\[ Q=500 n-n^{2} \\] and the amount of oil produced by each well ( \(q\) ) is given by \\[ q=\frac{Q}{n}=500-n \\] a. Describe the equilibrium output and the equilibrium number of wells in this perfectly competitive case. Is there a divergence between private and social marginal cost in the industry? b. Suppose now that the government nationalizes the oil field. How many oil wells should it operate? What will total output be? What will the output per well be? c. As an alternative to nationalization, the Utopian government is considering an annual license fee per well to discourage overdrilling. How large should this license fee be if it is to prompt the industry to drill the optimal number of wells?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free