Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Recall the Hotelling model of competition on a linear beach from Example \(15.5 .\) Suppose for simplicity that ice cream stands can locate only at the two ends of the line segment (zoning prohibits commercial development in the middle of the beach). This question asks you to analyze an entrydeterring strategy involving product proliferation. a. Consider the subgame in which firm \(A\) has two ice cream stands, one at each end of the beach, and \(B\) locates along with \(A\) at the right endpoint. What is the Nash equilibrium of this subgame? Hint: Bertrand competition ensues at the right endpoint. b. If \(B\) must sink an entry cost \(K_{B},\) would it choose to enter given that firm \(A\) is in both ends of the market and remains there after entry? c. Is \(A\) 's product proliferation strategy credible? Or would \(A\) exit the right end of the market after \(B\) enters? To answer these questions, compare \(A\) 's profits for the case in which it has a stand on the left side and both it and \(B\) have stands on the right to the case in which \(A\) has one stand on the left end and \(B\) has one stand on the right end (so \(B^{\prime}\) s entry has driven \(A\) out of the right side of the market).

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: The credibility of firm A's product proliferation strategy depends on its ability to commit to staying in the market and engaging in Bertrand competition even after firm B enters. If firm A can convince firm B of this, the strategy will be credible and effective for deterring entry. If not, the strategy will not be credible, and firm A would be better off exiting the right end of the market after firm B enters.

Step by step solution

01

a. Finding the Nash equilibrium in the subgame

In this subgame, firm A has two ice cream stands located at both ends of the beach. Firm B locates along with firm A at the right endpoint. Since firm A and firm B are competing for the consumers at the right endpoint, Bertrand competition will ensue. In Bertrand competition, firms compete on price and each firm undercuts the other until the price reaches the marginal cost of production (in this case, assume it to be zero). Therefore, the Nash equilibrium of this subgame is that both firm A and firm B charge a price equal to their marginal cost at the right endpoint of the beach, which is zero. Now, let's move to the second part.
02

b. Would firm B enter given the entry cost Kb?

By entering the market, firm B is expected to undertake an entry cost Kb. If firm A remains at both ends of the market and is engaged in Bertrand competition with firm B, we have already established that their price at the right endpoint will be the marginal cost, which is zero. Since firm B will not make any profit due to pricing at the marginal cost in this competitive scenario, it will be not be willing to enter the market and incur the entry cost Kb. In this case, firm B will choose not to enter the market. Finally, let's check if A's product proliferation strategy is credible.
03

c. Credibility of A's product proliferation strategy

To determine the credibility of A's strategy, compare A's profits in the following two cases: 1. A has a stand on the left side and both A and B have stands on the right 2. A has one stand on the left end and B has one stand on the right end In the first case, as we have found, firms A and B will engage in Bertrand competition, driving prices down to marginal cost and leaving both firms with zero profit at the right endpoint. However, firm A will still make profits from the left endpoint where it has a monopoly. In the second case, firm B's entry drives firm A out of the right side of the market, resulting in firm A holding a monopoly at the left end and firm B holding a monopoly at the right end of the market. In this scenario, both firms can charge prices above the marginal cost and make positive profits. Comparing these two cases, it is evident that firm A is better off with the proliferation strategy only if it can credibly commit to not exiting the right end of the market after firm B enters. Otherwise, A's profits are larger when it has a monopoly on just one end of the market and B has a monopoly on the other end. Therefore, the credibility of A's product proliferation strategy depends on its ability to commit to staying in the market after B enters. If A can convince B that it will remain at both ends of the market and engage in Bertrand competition even after B's entry, the strategy will be credible and effective for deterring entry. If not, the strategy will not be credible, and firm A would be better off exiting the right end of the market after B enters.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Bertrand Competition
Imagine two ice cream stands at the beach, each competing to attract sunbathers eager for a refreshing treat. In the world of economics, this scenario is akin to Bertrand competition, where businesses engage in fierce price wars to outdo each other.

In the classic Bertrand model, firms lower their prices to outcompete rivals, often reducing prices to the marginal cost of production. For our beach ice cream sellers, if one stand lowers prices to increase sales, the other is pressured to follow suit or risk losing customers. This process continues until prices cannot go any lower without incurring losses. At this point, they reach an equilibrium where both stands charge the same, lowest viable price.

This price-focused battle can lead to a situation where profits are minimal, leaving no room for new competitors to enter the market if they cannot match these low prices, especially after considering entry costs.
Nash Equilibrium
A Nash equilibrium is a concept within game theory where no participant can benefit by changing their strategy if the other participants keep theirs unchanged. It's like a stalemate in chess, where making a move doesn't necessarily improve your position because your opponent's moves counter yours effectively.

In the context of our ice cream stands at either end of the beach, the Nash equilibrium occurs when neither seller can lower their price further without making a loss. Assuming production costs are zero, they end up giving away the ice cream for free – a situation that clearly isn't profitable, but is stable because neither can undercut the other without incurring a loss.

This concept crucially illustrates that not every equilibrium is necessarily good for the firms involved, as a Nash equilibrium can correspond to a situation where firms make zero profits due to intense competition.
Product Proliferation Strategy
A product proliferation strategy involves introducing multiple products to the market, often variants of a core offering, to saturate a market and deter competition. Think of a popular video game console brand releasing numerous versions and bundles to maintain dominance on the shelves.

In our beach setting, Firm A uses product proliferation by placing a stand at both ends of the beach, attempting to cover the market entirely. This tactic could deter Firm B from entering since A's presence throughout the beach means that B’s potential for market share and profit is severely limited.

For such a strategy to be credible, Firm A must convincingly commit to maintaining stands on both ends, even if Firm B decides to enter the fray. If Firm B believes Firm A will retract one stand upon B’s entry, thereby lessening the intensity of competition, B might find it worthwhile to enter after all. In essence, a successful product proliferation strategy relies on commitment and the perception of that commitment by competitors.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Consider the following Bertrand game involving two firms producing differentiated products. Firms have no costs of production. Firm l's demand is \\[ q_{1}=1-p_{1}+b p_{2} \\] where \(b>0 .\) A symmetric equation holds for firm 2 's demand. a. Solve for the Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous price-choice game. b. Compute the firms' outputs and profits. c. Represent the equilibrium on a best-response function diagram. Show how an increase in \(b\) would change the equilibrium. Draw a representative isoprofit curve for firm 1

In this problem, we return to the question of shrouded product attributes and prices, introduced in Problem 6.14 and further analyzed in Problem \(14.13 .\) Here we will pursue the question of whether market forces can be counted on to attenuate consumer behavioral biases. In particular, whether competition and advertising can serve to unshroud previously shrouded prices. We will study a model inspired by Xavier Gabaix and David Laibson's influential article. \(^{19}\) A population of consumers (normalize their mass to 1 ) have gross surplus \(v\) for a homogeneous good produced by duopoly firms at constant marginal and average cost \(c .\) Firms \(i=1,2\) simultaneously post prices \(p_{i} .\) In addition to these posted prices, each firm \(i\) can add a shrouded fee \(s_{i},\) which are anticipated by some consumers but not others. For example, the fees could be for checked baggage associated with plane travel or for not making a minimum monthly payment on a credit card. A fraction \(\alpha\) are sophisticated consumers, who understand the equilibrium and anticipate equilibrium shrouded fees. At a small inconvenience cost \(e\), they are able to avoid the shrouded fee (packing only carry-ons in the airline example or being sure to make the minimum monthly payment in the credit-card example). The remaining fraction \(1-\alpha\) of consumers are myopic. They do not anticipate shrouded fees, only considering posted prices in deciding from which firm to buy. Their only way of avoiding the fee is void the entire transaction (saving the total expenditure \(p_{i}+s_{i}\) but forgoing surplus \(v\) ). Suppose firms choose posted prices simultaneously as in the Bertrand model. a. Argue that in equilibrium, \(p_{i}^{*}+s_{i}^{*}=v\) (at least as long as \(e\) is sufficiently small that firms do not try to induce sophisticated consumers not to avoid the shrouded fee). Compute the Nash equilibrium posted prices \(p_{i}^{*}\). (Hint: As in the standard Bertrand game, an undercutting argument suggests that a zero-profit condition is crucial in determining \(p_{i}^{*}\) here, too.) How do the posted prices compare to cost? Are they guaranteed to be positive? How is surplus allocated across consumers? b. Can you give examples of real-world products that seem to be priced as in part (a)? c. Suppose that one of the firms, say firm \(2,\) can deviate to an advertising strategy. Advertising has several effects. First, it converts myopic consumers into sophisticated ones (who rationally forecast shrouded fees and who can avoid them at cost \(e\) ). Second, it allows firm 2 to make both \(p_{2}\) and \(s_{2}\) transparent to all types of consumers. Show that this deviation is unprofitable if $$e<\left(\frac{1-\alpha}{\alpha}\right)(v-c)$$ d. Hence we have shown that even costless advertising need not result in unshrouding. Explain the forces leading advertising to be an unprofitable deviation. e. Return to the case in part (a) with no advertising, but now suppose firms cannot post negative prices. (One reason is that sophisticated consumers could exact huge losses by purchasing an untold number of units to earn the negative price, which are simply disposed of.) Compute the Nash equilibrium. How does it compare to part (a)? Can firms earn positive profits?

Suppose that firms' marginal and average costs are constant and equal to \(c\) and that inverse market demand is given by \(P=a-b Q,\) where \(a, b>0\) a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for a monopolist. Also calculate the monopolist's profit. b. Calculate the Nash equilibrium quantities for Cournot duopolists, which choose quantities for their identical products simultaneously. Also compute market output, market price, and firm and industry profits. c. Calculate the Nash equilibrium prices for Bertrand duopolists, which choose prices for their identical products simultaneously. Also compute firm and market output as well as firm and industry profits. d. Suppose now that there are \(n\) identical firms in a Cournot model. Compute the Nash equilibrium quantities as functions of \(n\). Also compute market output, market price, and firm and industry profits. e. Show that the monopoly outcome from part (a) can be reproduced in part (d) by setting \(n=1\), that the Cournot duopoly outcome from part (b) can be reproduced in part (d) by setting \(n=2\) in part (d), and that letting \(n\) approach infinity yields the same market price, output, and industry profit as in part (c).

Assume for simplicity that a monopolist has no costs of production and faces a demand curve given by \(Q=150-P\) a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for this monopolist. Also calculate the monopolist's profit. b. Suppose instead that there are two firms in the market facing the demand and cost conditions just described for their identical products. Firms choose quantities simultaneously as in the Cournot model. Compute the outputs in the Nash equilibrium. Also compute market output, price, and firm profits. c. Suppose the two firms choose prices simultaneously as in the Bertrand model. Compute the prices in the Nash equilibrium. Also compute firm output and profit as well as market output. d. Graph the demand curve and indicate where the market price-quantity combinations from parts (a)-(c) appear on the curve.

Recall Example \(15.6,\) which covers tacit collusion. Suppose (as in the example) that a medical device is produced at constant average and marginal cost of \(\$ 10\) and that the demand for the device is given by \\[ Q=5,000-100 P \\] The market meets each period for an infinite number of periods. The discount factor is \(\delta\) a. Suppose that \(n\) firms engage in Bertrand competition each period. Suppose it takes two periods to discover a deviation because it takes two periods to observe rivals' prices. Compute the discount factor needed to sustain collusion in a subgame-perfect equilibrium using grim strategies. b. Now restore the assumption that, as in Example 15.7 deviations are detected after just one period. Next, assume that \(n\) is not given but rather is determined by the number of firms that choose to enter the market in an initial stage in which entrants must sink a one-time cost \(K\) to participate in the market. Find an upper bound on \(n .\) Hint: Two conditions are involved.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free