Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Consider the following Bertrand game involving two firms producing differentiated products. Firms have no costs of production. Firm l's demand is \\[ q_{1}=1-p_{1}+b p_{2} \\] where \(b>0 .\) A symmetric equation holds for firm 2 's demand. a. Solve for the Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous price-choice game. b. Compute the firms' outputs and profits. c. Represent the equilibrium on a best-response function diagram. Show how an increase in \(b\) would change the equilibrium. Draw a representative isoprofit curve for firm 1

Short Answer

Expert verified
The Nash equilibrium is given by \((p_1^*, p_2^*)= (\frac{2}{b+1}, \frac{2}{b+1})\). When the differentiation parameter \(b\) increases, both firms' Nash equilibrium prices increase, as the products become closer substitutes.

Step by step solution

01

Derive the profit function for each firm

We are given the demand function for Firm 1 as \(q_1=1-p_1+bp_2\). Since the products are differentiated, we assume a symmetric demand function for Firm 2: \(q_2=1-p_2+bp_1\). Revenue for each firm is given by \(R_i = p_i q_i\) and since there are no costs associated with production, the profit for each firm is equal to its revenue. We derive the profit function for each firm as follows: Profit for Firm 1: \(\pi_1 = p_1 q_1 = p_1(1-p_1+bp_2)\) Profit for Firm 2: \(\pi_2 = p_2 q_2 = p_2(1-p_2+bp_1)\)
02

Derive the best response functions for each firm

To derive the best response functions, we find the first-order conditions of the profit functions with respect to the respective prices (Firm 1 with respect to \(p_1\) and Firm 2 with respect to \(p_2\)), set the first-order conditions to zero, and solve for the prices. For Firm 1: \(\frac{\partial \pi_1}{\partial p_1} = (1-p_1+bp_2) - p_1 = 0\) Solving for \(p_1\) gives the best-response function for Firm 1: \(p_1^*(p_2) = \frac{1+bp_2}{2}\) For Firm 2: \(\frac{\partial \pi_2}{\partial p_2} = (1-p_2+bp_1) - p_2 = 0\) Solving for \(p_2\) gives the best-response function for Firm 2: \(p_2^*(p_1) = \frac{1+bp_1}{2}\)
03

Find the Nash equilibrium

To find the Nash equilibrium, set each firm's price equal to its best-response function and solve for \(p_1\) and \(p_2\) simultaneously: \(p_1 = \frac{1+bp_2}{2}\) \(p_2 = \frac{1+bp_1}{2}\) Solve the system of equations for the prices: \(p_1 = \frac{1+b(\frac{1+bp_1}{2})}{2} \Rightarrow p_1 = \frac{2}{b+1}\) \(p_2 = \frac{1+b(\frac{1+bp_2}{2})}{2} \Rightarrow p_2 = \frac{2}{b+1}\) Since both prices are the same, the Nash equilibrium is given by \((p_1^*, p_2^*)= (\frac{2}{b+1}, \frac{2}{b+1})\)
04

Compute the firms' outputs and profits

To find the outputs for both firms, substitute the Nash equilibrium prices into the respective demand functions: For Firm 1: \(q_1^* = 1 - \frac{2}{b+1} +b (\frac{2}{b+1}) \Rightarrow q_1^* = \frac{2b}{(b+1)^2}\) For Firm 2: \(q_2^* = 1 - \frac{2}{b+1} +b (\frac{2}{b+1}) \Rightarrow q_2^* = \frac{2b}{(b+1)^2}\) Since both outputs are the same, the equilibrium outputs are given by \((q_1^*, q_2^*)= (\frac{2b}{(b+1)^2}, \frac{2b}{(b+1)^2})\) To find the profits for both firms, substitute the Nash equilibrium prices and outputs into the respective profit functions: Profit for Firm 1: \(\pi_1^* = (\frac{2}{b+1}) (\frac{2b}{(b+1)^2}) \Rightarrow \pi_1^* = \frac{4b}{(b+1)^3}\) Profit for Firm 2: \(\pi_2^* = (\frac{2}{b+1}) (\frac{2b}{(b+1)^2}) \Rightarrow \pi_2^* = \frac{4b}{(b+1)^3}\) Since both profits are the same, the equilibrium profits are given by \((\pi_1^*, \pi_2^*)= (\frac{4b}{(b+1)^3}, \frac{4b}{(b+1)^3})\)
05

Graphical representation, changes in \(b\), and isoprofit curves

A graphical representation of the best-response functions, equilibrium, changes in \(b\), and isoprofit curves should include the following: 1. Plot the best-response function for each firm (Firm 1 on the \(p_1\)-axis and Firm 2 on the \(p_2\)-axis) as straight lines with a positive slope, intersecting at the Nash equilibrium \((\frac{2}{b+1}, \frac{2}{b+1})\). 2. Demonstrate the effect of an increase in \(b\) on the equilibrium by showing that an increase in \(b\) leads to an increase in both firms' Nash equilibrium prices and a decrease in market share for both firms (as each firm becomes closer substitutes when \(b\) increases). 3. Plot a representative isoprofit curve for Firm 1, which should be an upward-sloping curve in the \(p_1\)-\(p_2\) plane, illustrating the combinations of \(p_1\) and \(p_2\) that yield the same profit level for Firm 1.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Assume as in Problem 15.1 that two firms with no production costs, facing demand \(Q=150-P\), choose quantities \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\) a. Compute the subgame-perfect equilibrium of the Stackelberg version of the game in which firm 1 chooses \(q_{1}\) first and then firm 2 chooses \(q_{2}\) b. Now add an entry stage after firm 1 chooses \(q_{1}\). In this stage, firm 2 decides whether to enter. If it enters, then it must sink cost \(K_{2},\) after which it is allowed to choose \(q_{2}\) Compute the threshold value of \(K_{2}\) above which firm 1 prefers to deter firm 2 's entry. c. Represent the Cournot, Stackelberg, and entry-deterrence outcomes on a best-response function diagram.

Recall Example \(15.6,\) which covers tacit collusion. Suppose (as in the example) that a medical device is produced at constant average and marginal cost of \(\$ 10\) and that the demand for the device is given by \\[ Q=5,000-100 P \\] The market meets each period for an infinite number of periods. The discount factor is \(\delta\) a. Suppose that \(n\) firms engage in Bertrand competition each period. Suppose it takes two periods to discover a deviation because it takes two periods to observe rivals' prices. Compute the discount factor needed to sustain collusion in a subgame-perfect equilibrium using grim strategies. b. Now restore the assumption that, as in Example 15.7 deviations are detected after just one period. Next, assume that \(n\) is not given but rather is determined by the number of firms that choose to enter the market in an initial stage in which entrants must sink a one-time cost \(K\) to participate in the market. Find an upper bound on \(n .\) Hint: Two conditions are involved.

This question will explore signaling when entry deterrence is impossible; thus, the signaling firm accommodates its rival's entry. Assume deterrence is impossible because the two firms do not pay a sunk cost to enter or remain in the market. The setup of the model will follow Example \(15.4,\) so the calculations there will aid the solution of this problem. In particular, firm \(i\) 's demand is given by \\[ q_{i}=a_{i}-p_{i}+\frac{p_{j}}{2} \\] where \(a_{i}\) is product \(i\) 's attribute (say, quality). Production is costless. Firm l's attribute can be one of two values: either \(a_{1}=1,\) in which case we say firm 1 is the low type, or \(a_{1}=2\) in which case we say it is the high type. Assume there is no discounting across periods for simplicity. a. Compute the Nash equilibrium of the game of complete information in which firm 1 is the high type and firm 2 knows that firm 1 is the high type. b. Compute the Nash equilibrium of the game in which firm 1 is the low type and firm 2 knows that firm 1 is the low type. c. Solve for the Bayesian-Nash equilibrium of the game of incomplete information in which firm 1 can be either type with equal probability. Firm 1 knows its type, but firm 2 only knows the probabilities. Because we did not spend time in this chapter on Bayesian games, you may want to consult Chapter 8 (especially Example 8.6 ). Which of firm 1's types gains from incomplete information? Which type would prefer complete information (and thus would have an incentive to signal its type if possible \() ?\) Does firm 2 earn more profit on average under complete information or under incomplete information? e. Consider a signaling variant of the model chat has two periods. Firms 1 and 2 choose prices in the first period when firm 2 has incomplete information about firm 1 's type. Firm 2 observes firm 1's price in this period and uses the information to update its beliefs about firm l's type Then firms engage in another period of price competi tion. Show that there is a separating equilibrium in which each type of firm 1 charges the same prices as computed in part (d). You may assume that, if firm 1 chooses an out-of-equilibrium price in the first period, then firm 2 believes that firm 1 is the low type with probability \(1 .\) Hint To prove the existence of a separating equilibrium, show that the loss to the low type from trying to pool in the first period exceeds the second-period gain from having con vinced firm 2 that it is the high type. Use your answers from parts (a)-(d) where possible to aid in your solution.

Recall the Hotelling model of competition on a linear beach from Example \(15.5 .\) Suppose for simplicity that ice cream stands can locate only at the two ends of the line segment (zoning prohibits commercial development in the middle of the beach). This question asks you to analyze an entrydeterring strategy involving product proliferation. a. Consider the subgame in which firm \(A\) has two ice cream stands, one at each end of the beach, and \(B\) locates along with \(A\) at the right endpoint. What is the Nash equilibrium of this subgame? Hint: Bertrand competition ensues at the right endpoint. b. If \(B\) must sink an entry cost \(K_{B},\) would it choose to enter given that firm \(A\) is in both ends of the market and remains there after entry? c. Is \(A\) 's product proliferation strategy credible? Or would \(A\) exit the right end of the market after \(B\) enters? To answer these questions, compare \(A\) 's profits for the case in which it has a stand on the left side and both it and \(B\) have stands on the right to the case in which \(A\) has one stand on the left end and \(B\) has one stand on the right end (so \(B^{\prime}\) s entry has driven \(A\) out of the right side of the market).

In this problem, we return to the question of shrouded product attributes and prices, introduced in Problem 6.14 and further analyzed in Problem \(14.13 .\) Here we will pursue the question of whether market forces can be counted on to attenuate consumer behavioral biases. In particular, whether competition and advertising can serve to unshroud previously shrouded prices. We will study a model inspired by Xavier Gabaix and David Laibson's influential article. \(^{19}\) A population of consumers (normalize their mass to 1 ) have gross surplus \(v\) for a homogeneous good produced by duopoly firms at constant marginal and average cost \(c .\) Firms \(i=1,2\) simultaneously post prices \(p_{i} .\) In addition to these posted prices, each firm \(i\) can add a shrouded fee \(s_{i},\) which are anticipated by some consumers but not others. For example, the fees could be for checked baggage associated with plane travel or for not making a minimum monthly payment on a credit card. A fraction \(\alpha\) are sophisticated consumers, who understand the equilibrium and anticipate equilibrium shrouded fees. At a small inconvenience cost \(e\), they are able to avoid the shrouded fee (packing only carry-ons in the airline example or being sure to make the minimum monthly payment in the credit-card example). The remaining fraction \(1-\alpha\) of consumers are myopic. They do not anticipate shrouded fees, only considering posted prices in deciding from which firm to buy. Their only way of avoiding the fee is void the entire transaction (saving the total expenditure \(p_{i}+s_{i}\) but forgoing surplus \(v\) ). Suppose firms choose posted prices simultaneously as in the Bertrand model. a. Argue that in equilibrium, \(p_{i}^{*}+s_{i}^{*}=v\) (at least as long as \(e\) is sufficiently small that firms do not try to induce sophisticated consumers not to avoid the shrouded fee). Compute the Nash equilibrium posted prices \(p_{i}^{*}\). (Hint: As in the standard Bertrand game, an undercutting argument suggests that a zero-profit condition is crucial in determining \(p_{i}^{*}\) here, too.) How do the posted prices compare to cost? Are they guaranteed to be positive? How is surplus allocated across consumers? b. Can you give examples of real-world products that seem to be priced as in part (a)? c. Suppose that one of the firms, say firm \(2,\) can deviate to an advertising strategy. Advertising has several effects. First, it converts myopic consumers into sophisticated ones (who rationally forecast shrouded fees and who can avoid them at cost \(e\) ). Second, it allows firm 2 to make both \(p_{2}\) and \(s_{2}\) transparent to all types of consumers. Show that this deviation is unprofitable if $$e<\left(\frac{1-\alpha}{\alpha}\right)(v-c)$$ d. Hence we have shown that even costless advertising need not result in unshrouding. Explain the forces leading advertising to be an unprofitable deviation. e. Return to the case in part (a) with no advertising, but now suppose firms cannot post negative prices. (One reason is that sophisticated consumers could exact huge losses by purchasing an untold number of units to earn the negative price, which are simply disposed of.) Compute the Nash equilibrium. How does it compare to part (a)? Can firms earn positive profits?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free