Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

A monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \(A C=M C=5 .\) The firm faces a market demand curve given by \(Q=53-P\). a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the monopolist. Also calculate the monopolist's profits. b. What output level would be produced by this industry under perfect competition (where price \(=\) marginal \(\operatorname{cost}) ?\) c. Calculate the consumer surplus obtained by consumers in case (b). Show that this exceeds the sum of the monopolist's profits and the consumer surplus received in case (a). What is the value of the "deadweight loss" from monopolization?

Short Answer

Expert verified
#Step 1: Find the Marginal Revenue for the Monopolist The inverse demand function is given by: \(P = 53 - Q\). The total revenue (TR) is: \(TR = (53 - Q) * Q\). Differentiating TR with respect to Q, we get: \(MR = \frac{d(TR)}{d(Q)} = (53 - 2Q)\). #Step 2: Calculate the Monopolist's Profit Maximization Condition Setting MR equal to MC, we have: \(53 - 2Q = 5\). #Step 3: Calculate the Profit-Maximizing Quantity and Price Solving the equation from Step 2: \(2Q = 48\) \(Q = 24\). Substituting the value of Q into the inverse demand function: \(P = 53 - 24 = 29\). Thus, the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the monopolist is P = $29, and Q = 24. #Step 4: Calculate the Profits for the Monopolist Total cost (TC) = $5 * 24 = $120. Total revenue (TR) = $(53 - 24) * 24 = $696\). Profits = TR - TC = $696 - $120 = $576. #Step 5: Calculate the Output Level Under Perfect Competition Under perfect competition, P = MC, so P = $5. Substituting the price back into the inverse demand function: \(5 = 53 - Q\) \(Q = 53 - 5 = 48\). The output level under perfect competition is Q = 48. #Step 6: Calculate the Consumer Surplus in Case (b) Consumer Surplus = (base * height) / 2. The base of the triangle is equal to the difference between the price and the intercept of the demand curve: (53 - 5). The height is equal to the quantity produced under perfect competition: 48. Consumer Surplus = \((53 - 5) * 48 / 2 = 48 * 24 = $1,152\). #Step 7: Compare Consumer Surplus and Monopolist's Profits From Steps 4 and 6: Monopolist's profits = $576. Consumer surplus in case (a) = $1,152 - $576 = $576. The sum of the monopolist's profits and consumer surplus in case (a) ($1,152) is less than the consumer surplus in case (b) ($1,152). #Step 8: Calculate Deadweight Loss Deadweight loss = Consumer surplus in case (b) - (Monopolist's profits + Consumer surplus in case (a)) = $1,152 - $1,152 = $0. Therefore, there is no deadweight loss from monopolization in this case.

Step by step solution

01

Find the Marginal Revenue for the Monopolist

To find the marginal revenue (MR) for the monopolist, first, we need to find the inverse demand equation, where the price is expressed in terms of Q. From the given demand equation, \(Q=53-P\), we can rearrange the terms to get the price equation: \(P = 53 - Q\). Now, we find the total revenue (TR), which is given by: \(TR = P * Q\). Substituting the inverse demand function, we get \(TR = (53 - Q) * Q\). To find the marginal revenue (MR), we need to differentiate the total revenue (TR) with respect to quantity Q: \(MR = d(TR)/dQ\).
02

Calculate the Monopolist's Profit Maximization Condition

To find the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the monopolist, we need to set MR equal to MC and solve for the quantity Q. We are given that \(MC = 5\). Next, we equate MR and MC: \(MR = 5\).
03

Calculate the Profit-Maximizing Quantity and Price

By solving the equation from Step 2, we can find the profit-maximizing quantity for the monopolist. Then we can substitute the value of Q back into the inverse demand function to find the corresponding price.
04

Calculate the Profits for the Monopolist

To calculate the profits for the monopolist, we need to find the total revenue (TR) and the total cost (TC) at the profit-maximizing quantity. Profits = TR - TC. We have found \(TR = (53-Q) * Q\) in Step 1. And, since the average cost (AC) is constant at \(5, TC = AC * Q = 5 * Q\). We can substitute the value of Q back into both TR and TC and then find the monopolist's profits by subtracting TC from TR.
05

Calculate the Output Level Under Perfect Competition

Under perfect competition, firms produce at the level where price equals marginal cost: P = MC. Since the marginal cost (MC) is constant at \(5\), in perfect competition, the price is equal to \(5\). We can substitute the price back into the inverse demand function and find the output level Q.
06

Calculate the Consumer Surplus in Case (b)

To find the consumer surplus in a perfectly competitive market, we need to find the area of the triangle between the market price and the demand curve. Consumer Surplus = (base * height) / 2. The base of the triangle is equal to the difference between the price and the intercept of the demand curve, and the height is equal to the quantity produced under perfect competition. Now we can calculate the value of the consumer surplus.
07

Compare Consumer Surplus and Monopolist's Profits

In this step, we need to show that the sum of the monopolist's profits and consumer surplus in case (a) is less than the consumer surplus obtained by the consumers in case (b). We can compare the results found in Steps 4 and 6 to do this.
08

Calculate Deadweight Loss

To find the deadweight loss from monopolization, we need to find the difference between the consumer surplus in case (b) and the sum of the monopolist's profits and consumer surplus in case (a). We can use the results obtained in Steps 4 and 6 to calculate the deadweight loss.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose a perfectly competitive industry can produce widgets at a constant marginal cost of \(\$ 10\) per unit. Monopolized marginal costs increase to \(\$ 12\) per unit because \(\$ 2\) per unit must be paid to lobbyists to retain the widget producers' favored position. Suppose the market demand for widgets is given by \\[ Q_{D}=1,000-50 P \\] a. Calculate the perfectly competitive and monopoly outputs and prices. b. Calculate the total loss of consumer surplus from monopolization of widget production. c. Graph your results and explain how they differ from the usual analysis.

A single firm monopolizes the entire market for widgets and can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \\[ A C=M C=10 \\] Originally, the firm faces a market demand curve given by \\[ Q=60-P \\] a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the firm. What are the firm's profits? b. Now assume that the market demand curve shifts outward (becoming steeper) and is given by \\[ Q=45-0.5 P \\] What is the firm's profit-maximizing price-quantity combination now? What are the firm's profits? c. Instead of the assumptions of part (b), assume that the market demand curve shifts outward (becoming flatter) and is given by \\[ Q=100-2 P \\] What is the firm's profit-maximizing price-quantity combination now? What are the firm's profits? d. Graph the three different situations of parts (a), (b), and (c). Using your results, explain why there is no real supply curve for a monopoly.

Some firms employ the marketing strategy of posting a low price for the good, but then tack on hidden fees or high prices for add-ons that can add up to an "all-in" price that is exorbitant compared to the posted price. A television ad may blare that a perpetually sharp knife sells for \(\$ 20,\) leaving the additional \(\$ 10\) handling charge-or worse, that the \(\$ 20\) is just one of three installments-for the small print. A laser printer printing photo-quality color prints may seem like a bargain at \(\$ 300\) if one doesn't consider that the five toner cartridges must be replaced each year at \(\$ 100\) each. If consumers understand and account for these additional expenses, we are firmly in a neoclassical model, which can be analyzed using standard methods. Behavioral economists worry about the possibility that unsophisticated consumers may underestimate or even ignore these shrouded prices and firms do their best to keep it that way. This question introduces a model of shrouded prices and analyzes their efficiency consequences. a. Consumers' demand for a good whose price they perceive to be \(P\) is given by \(Q=10-P .\) A monopolist produces the good at constant average and marginal cost equal to \(\$ 6 .\) Compute the monopoly price, quantity, profit, consumer surplus, and welfare (the sum of consumer surplus and profit) assuming the perceived is the same as the actual price, so there is no shrouding. b. Now assume that while the perceived price is still \(P\), the actual price charged by the monopolist is \(P+s,\) where \(s\) is the shrouded part, which goes unrecognized by consumers. Compute the monopoly price, quantity, and profit assuming the same demand and cost as in part (a). What amount of shrouding does the firm prefer? c. Compute the consumer surplus (CS) associated with the outcome in (b). This requires some care because consumers spend more than they expect to. Letting \(P_{s}\) and \(Q_{s}\) be the equilibrium price and quantity charged by the monopoly with shrouded prices, \\[ C S=\int_{0}^{Q} P(Q) d Q-P_{s} Q_{s} \\] This equals gross consumer surplus (the area under inverse demand up to the quantity sold) less actual rather than perceived expenditures. d. Compute welfare. Find the welfare-maximizing level of shrouding. Explain why this is positive rather than zero. e. Return to the case of no shrouding in part (a) but now assume the government offers a subsidy s. Show that the welfare-maximizing subsidy equals welfare-maximizing level of shrouding found in part (d). Are the distributional consequences (surplus going to consumers, firm, and government) the same in the two cases? Use the connection between shrouding and a subsidy to argue informally that any amount of shrouding will be inefficient in a perfectly competitive market.

Suppose a monopolist produces alkaline batteries that may have various useful lifetimes \((X) .\) Suppose also that consumers' (inverse) demand depends on batteries' lifetimes and quantity (Q) purchased according to the function \\[ P(Q, X)=g(X \cdot Q) \\] where \(g^{\prime} < 0 .\) That is, consumers care only about the product of quantity times lifetime: They are willing to pay equally for many short-lived batteries or few long-lived ones. Assume also that battery costs are given by \\[ C(Q, X)=C(X) Q \\] where \(C^{\prime}(X )> 0 .\) Show that, in this case, the monopoly will opt for the same level of \(X\) as does a competitive industry even though levels of output and prices may differ. Explain your result. Hint: Treat \(X Q\) as a composite commodity.

Suppose a monopoly can produce any level of output it wishes at a constant marginal (and average) cost of \(\$ 5\) per unit. Assume the monopoly sells its goods in two different markets separated by some distance. The demand curve in the first market is given by \\[ Q_{1}=55-P_{1} \\] and the demand curve in the second market is given by \\[ Q_{2}=70-2 P_{2} \\] a. If the monopolist can maintain the separation between the two markets, what level of output should be produced in each market, and what price will prevail in each market? What are total profits in this situation? b. How would your answer change if it costs demanders only \(\$ 4\) to transport goods between the two markets? What would be the monopolist's new profit level in this situation? c. How would your answer change if transportation costs were zero and then the firm was forced to follow a single-price policy? d. Now assume the two different markets 1 and 2 are just two individual consumers. Suppose the firm could adopt a linear two-part tariff under which marginal prices charged to the two consumers must be equal but their lump-sum entry fees might vary. What pricing policy should the firm follow?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free