Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The domestic demand for portable radios is given by \\[ Q=D(P)=5,000-100 P \\] where price \((P)\) is measured in dollars and quantity (Q) is measured in thousands of radios per year. The domestic supply curve for radios is given by \\[ Q=S(P)=150 P \\] a. What is the domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market? b. Suppose portable radios can be imported at a world price of \(\$ 10\) per radio. If trade were unencumbered, what would the new market equilibrium be? How many portable radios would be imported? c. If domestic portable radio producers succeeded in having a \(\$ 5\) tariff implemented, how would this change the market equilibrium? How much would be collected in tariff revenues? How much consumer surplus would be transferred to domestic producers? What would the deadweight loss from the tariff be? d. How would your results from part (c) be changed if the government reached an agreement with foreign suppliers to "voluntarily" limit the portable radios they export to 1,250,000 per year? Explain how this differs from the case of a tariff.

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary, the domestic equilibrium for portable radios is at a price of $20 and a quantity of 3000 radios per year. When free trade is introduced, the new market equilibrium price drops to $10, and the total quantity increases to 4000 radios, with 2500 radios imported. With the implementation of a $5 tariff, the new market equilibrium shifts to a price of $15 and a total quantity of 3500 radios, with 1250 radios imported. At this point, the tariff revenue equals $6250, the consumer surplus transferred is $5000, and the deadweight loss is $3125. In the case of voluntary export restraints, the market will experience a similar effect as the tariff scenario, with an increase in domestic price and a decrease in imported radios. However, the deadweight loss would be larger compared to the tariff scenario, as there will be no tariff revenues to compensate for the increase in prices caused by voluntary restraints.

Step by step solution

01

a. Domestic Equilibrium

To find the domestic equilibrium, we need to equate the domestic demand and supply functions: $$ 5000 - 100 P = 150 P $$ Now let's solve for \(P\): $$ 5000 = 250 P $$ $$ P = 20 $$ Now, let's calculate the equilibrium quantity \(Q\) by substituting the price \(P\) into either the demand or supply function: $$ Q = 5000 - 100(20) = 3000 $$ The domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market is \(P = \$ 20\) and \(Q = 3000\) radios per year.
02

b. New Market Equilibrium with Free Trade

With free trade, the world price is \(P_W = \$ 10\). To find the new market equilibrium, we need to calculate the domestic demand and supply at this price: Demand at \(P_W = 10\): $$ Q_D = 5000 - 100(10) = 4000 $$ Supply at \(P_W = 10\): $$ Q_S = 150(10) = 1500 $$ Since domestic demand is greater than domestic supply, portable radios will be imported. The new market equilibrium is \(P = \$ 10\) and \(Q = 4000\) radios, with 2500 radios imported (\(4000 - 1500\)).
03

c. Market Equilibrium with $5 Tariff

With a \(5 tariff, the import price becomes \)P_T = \$ 15$. We need to calculate the new domestic demand and supply at this price: Demand at \(P_T = 15\): $$ Q_D = 5000 - 100(15) = 3500 $$ Supply at \(P_T = 15\): $$ Q_S = 150(15) = 2250 $$ The new market equilibrium with the tariff is \(P = \$ 15\) and \(Q = 3500\) radios, with 1250 radios imported (\(3500 - 2250\)). Now let's find the tariff revenues, consumer surplus transferred, and deadweight loss: Tariff revenues: \((\$ 5) \times (1250) = \$ 6250\). Consumer surplus transferred: The price increased from \(\$ 10\) to \(\$ 15\), so the consumers lose \(\$ 5\) per radio on 1000 radios (the increased quantity of domestic production). Thus, the consumer surplus transferred is \(\$ 5 \times 1000 = \$ 5000\). Deadweight loss: The rectangle's width and height denote the change in price (from \(\$10\) to \(\$15\), or \(\$5\)) and the change in import quantity (from 2500 to 1250, or 1250), respectively. The deadweight loss is: $$ Deadweight\, Loss = \frac{1}{2} \times 5 \times 1250 = \$ 3125 $$
04

d. Voluntary Export Restraint

If the government reaches an agreement with foreign suppliers to voluntarily limit the portable radios they export to 1,250,000 per year (we assume 1 unit = 1000 radios, so 1250 units per year), this would affect the market equilibrium by restricting the quantity supplied by foreign suppliers. With a constrained supply of imported radios, the domestic price will increase due to the reduced competition from imports. The effects on the market will be similar to those of a tariff, with an increase in the domestic price and a decrease in the quantity of imported radios. However, the major difference is that instead of tariff revenues collected by the government, there will be no added income, as prices are only increased due to the voluntary restraint agreement. This results in a larger deadweight loss compared to the case with a tariff, as the domestic market faces even higher prices without the benefit of tariff revenues.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Market Equilibrium
Market equilibrium is a core concept in microeconomic theory where the quantity demanded by consumers meets the quantity supplied by producers, resulting in a stable market price. For example, consider the case of portable radios where the demand is represented by the equation \( Q=D(P)=5,000-100P \), and supply is \( Q=S(P)=150P \). To find where the market rests without any outside intervention, we equate the demand and supply to find the equilibrium price \( P \). Solving \( 5000 - 100P = 150P \) gives us \( P = 20 \), and at this price, the equilibrium quantity is 3000 thousand radios per year. It's at this point that the market naturally balances itself; no excess supply or unmet demand exists.

Understanding equilibrium helps to predict the consequences of market changes, such as introducing tariffs or trade agreements. When changes arise, like a world market price or an imposed tariff, the market strives to reach a new equilibrium, giving us insight into how such disruptions can affect both producers and consumers.
Tariffs and Trade
In the context of tariffs and trade, when a country allows its citizens to trade freely, the world price dictates market dynamics. In the example of portable radios, if they could be imported at a world price of \( P_W = \(10 \), below the domestic equilibrium of \( \)20 \), consumers would opt for the cheaper imports. This causes a new market equilibrium where domestic supply decreases, demand increases, and the import of additional radios becomes necessary to satisfy the excess demand.

When tariffs are introduced, such as a \( \(5 \) tariff per radio, this raises the world price to \( P_T = \)15 \), reducing imports and raising domestic prices, altering the market equilibrium again. Tariffs serve as a tool to protect domestic industries by making imported goods more expensive but also result in higher prices for consumers. It illustrates the delicate balance policymakers must maintain while considering tariffs on trade, where protecting domestic industries can have far-reaching implications on market equilibrium and consumer costs.
Consumer Surplus
Consumer surplus is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay and what they actually pay. It represents the economic benefit to consumers, as they can purchase products for less than their maximum willingness to pay. For the portable radios, when the price is at the world market level of \( \(10 \), the consumer surplus is at its peak, because consumers enjoy lower prices.

When a tariff is imposed, raising the price to \( P_T = \)15 \), the consumer surplus is reduced. This is because buyers now pay more for the same product, reducing the economical benefit they previously enjoyed. The consumer surplus that is 'transferred' to domestic producers, measured as the increase in price times the increase in the quantity of domestic production due to the tariff, is one way to gauge the cost of such trade policies to consumers. The reduction in consumer surplus is a significant consideration when evaluating the impact of tariffs.
Deadweight Loss
Deadweight loss occurs when market inefficiency creates a loss of economic welfare. In cases where tariffs are applied, such as the \( \(5 \) tariff on portable radios, a deadweight loss arises. This loss is quantified by the loss in consumer and producer surplus that is not offset by the gain in tariff revenue. It represents the economic value that is simply lost to society because the tariff reduces the quantity traded below what the market would have determined in a free trade scenario.

The calculation of the deadweight loss involves the area of a triangle formed by the price increase and the reduction in trade volume. For instance, with the tariff, a rectangle's area under the demand curve represents lost consumer surplus, while a triangle's area represents the deadweight loss due to decreased imports. Specifically, the deadweight loss resulting from the \( \)5 \) tariff on portable radios would be \( \frac{1}{2} \times 5 \times 1250 = $3125 \), reflecting the inefficiency and reduced consumer welfare imposed by the tariff.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The handmade snuffbox industry is composed of 100 identical firms, each having short-run total costs given by \\[ S T C=0.5 q^{2}+10 q+5 \\] and short-run marginal costs given by \\[ S M C=q+10 \\] where \(q\) is the output of snuffboxes per day. a What is the short-run supply curve for each snuffbox maker? What is the short-run supply curve for the market as a whole? b. Suppose the demand for total snuffbox production is given by \\[ Q=D(P)=1,100-50 P \\] What will be the equilibrium in this marketplace? What will each firm's total short-run profits be? c. Graph the market equilibrium and compute total shortrun producer surplus in this case. d. Show that the total producer surplus you calculated in part (c) is equal to total industry profits plus industry short-run fixed costs. c. Suppose the government imposed a \(\$ 3\) tax on snuffboxes. How would this tax change the market equilibrium? f. How would the burden of this tax be shared between snuffbox buyers and sellers? g. Calculate the total loss of producer surplus as a result of the taxation of snuffboxes. Show that this loss equals the change in total short-run profits in the snuffbox industry. Why do fixed costs not enter into this computation of the change in short-run producer surplus?

A perfectly competitive industry has a large number of potential entrants. Each firm has an identical cost structure such that long-run average cost is minimized at an output of 20 units \(\left(q_{i}=20\right) .\) The minimum average cost is \(\$ 10\) per unit. Total market demand is given by \\[ Q=D(P)=1,500-50 P \\] a. What is the industry's long-run supply schedule? b. What is the long-run equilibrium price \(\left(P^{*}\right) ?\) The total industry output \(\left(Q^{*}\right) ?\) The output of each firm \(\left(q^{*}\right) ?\) The number of firms? The profits of each firm? c. The short-run total cost function associated with each firm's long-run equilibrium output is given by \\[ C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+200 \\] Calculate the short-run average and marginal cost function. At what output level does short-run average cost reach a minimum? d. Calculate the short-run supply function for each firm and the industry short-run supply function. c. Suppose now that the market demand function shifts upward to \(Q=D(P)=2,000-50 P\). Using this new demand curve, answer part (b) for the very short run when firms cannot change their outputs. f. In the short run, use the industry short-run supply function to recalculate the answers to (b). g. What is the new long-run equilibrium for the industry?

Suppose there are 1,000 identical firms producing diamonds. Let the total cost function for each firm be given by \\[ C(q, w)=q^{2}+w q \\] where \(q\) is the firm's output level and \(w\) is the wage rate of diamond cutters. a. If \(w=10,\) what will be the firm's (short-run) supply curve? What is the industry's supply curve? How many diamonds will be produced at a price of 20 each? How many more diamonds would be produced at a price of \(21 ?\) b. Suppose the wages of diamond cutters depend on the total quantity of diamonds produced, and suppose the form of this relationship is given by \\[ w=0.002 Q \\] here \(Q\) represents total industry output, which is 1,000 times the output of the typical firm. In this situation, show that the firm's marginal cost (and short-run supply) curve depends on \(Q\). What is the industry supply curve? How much will be produced at a price of \(20 ?\) How much more will be produced at a price of \(21 ?\) What do you conclude about the shape of the short-run supply curve?

Suppose there are 100 identical firms in a perfectly competitive industry. Each firm has a short-run total cost function of the form \\[ C(q)=\frac{1}{300} q^{3}+0.2 q^{2}+4 q+10 \\] a. Calculate the firm's short-run supply curve with \(q\) as a function of market price \((P)\) b. On the assumption that firms" output decisions do not affect their costs, calculate the short-run industry supply curve c. Suppose market demand is given by \(Q=-200 P+8,000\) What will be the short- run equilibrium price-quantity combination?

Suppose that the market demand for a product is given by \(Q_{D}=D(P)=A-B P\). Suppose also that the typical firm's cost function is given by \(C(q)=k+a q+b q^{2}\) a. Compute the long-run equilibrium output and price for the typical firm in this market. b. Calculate the equilibrium number of firms in this market as a function of all the parameters in this problem. c. Describe how changes in the demand parameters \(A\) and \(B\) affect the equilibrium number of firms in this market. Explain your results intuitively. d. Describe how the parameters of the typical firm's cost function affect the long-run equilibrium number of firms in this example. Explain your results intuitively.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free