Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose there are 100 identical firms in a perfectly competitive industry. Each firm has a short-run total cost function of the form \\[ C(q)=\frac{1}{300} q^{3}+0.2 q^{2}+4 q+10 \\] a. Calculate the firm's short-run supply curve with \(q\) as a function of market price \((P)\) b. On the assumption that firms" output decisions do not affect their costs, calculate the short-run industry supply curve c. Suppose market demand is given by \(Q=-200 P+8,000\) What will be the short- run equilibrium price-quantity combination?

Short Answer

Expert verified
Based on the given information about a perfectly competitive market with 100 identical firms, the short-run equilibrium price-quantity combination is (4.71, 7,100). This is determined by first calculating the firm's marginal cost and equating it to the market price, leading to the firm's short-run supply curve. Afterward, the short-run industry supply curve is found by multiplying the firm's supply curve by the number of firms in the industry. Finally, the equilibrium is found by equating the industry supply curve to the market demand curve.

Step by step solution

01

Calculate the marginal cost of the firm

To find the marginal cost of the firm, we need to differentiate the total cost function with respect to the quantity \((q)\). The total cost function is given as follows: \[C(q)=\frac{1}{300} q^{3}+0.2 q^{2}+4 q+10\] Now we find the derivative of this function with respect to \(q\): \[\frac{dC}{dq} = MC(q) = \frac{1}{100} q^{2} + 0.4 q + 4\]
02

Calculate the firm's short-run supply curve

In a perfectly competitive market, the firms are price takers, meaning that they equate the marginal cost to the market price \((P)\). So, we will set the marginal cost function equal to the market price to find the firm's short-run supply curve: \[P = \frac{1}{100} q^{2} + 0.4 q + 4\] Now, we can rearrange this equation to make \(q\) a function of \(P\): \[q(P) = 100(P - 4) - 0.4q\] So, the firm's short-run supply curve is given by: \[q(P) = 100(P - 4)\]
03

Calculate the short-run industry supply curve

To find the short-run industry supply curve, we need to multiply the firm's supply curve by the number of firms in the industry, which in this case is 100: \[Q_s(P) = 100 \cdot q(P) = 100 \cdot 100(P - 4)\] Therefore, the short-run industry supply curve is: \[Q_s(P) = 10,000(P - 4)\]
04

Find the short-run equilibrium price-quantity combination

To find the equilibrium price and quantity, we need to equate the industry supply curve to the market demand curve, which is given as \(Q=(-200P+8,000)\). When we set these two functions equal, we have: \[10,000(P - 4) = -200P + 8,000\] Solving for the market price \(P\): \[10,000P - 40,000 = -200P + 8,000\] \[10,200P = 48,000\] \[P = \frac{48,000}{10,200}\] \[P = 4.71\] Now that we have the equilibrium price, we can find the equilibrium quantity by plugging the equilibrium price back into either the industry supply curve or the market demand curve. We will use the industry supply curve: \[Q_s(4.71) = 10,000(4.71 - 4)\] \[Q_s = 10,000(0.71)\] \[Q_s = 7,100\] So, the short-run equilibrium price-quantity combination is \((P, Q) = (4.71, 7,100)\).

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that the demand for stilts is given by \\[ Q=D(P)=1,500-50 P \\] and that the long-run total operating costs of each stiltmaking firm in a competitive industry are given by \\[ C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q \\] Entrepreneurial talent for stilt making is scarce. The supply curve for entrepreneurs is given by \\[ Q_{s}=0.25 w \\] where \(w\) is the annual wage paid. Suppose also that each stilt-making firm requires one (and only one) entrepreneur (hence the quantity of entrepreneurs hired is equal to the number of firms). Long-run total costs for each firm are then given by \\[ C(q, w)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+w \\] a What is the long-run equilibrium quantity of stilts produced? How many stilts are produced by each firm? What is the long-run equilibrium price of stilts? How many firms will there be? How many entrepreneurs will be hired, and what is their wage? b. Suppose that the demand for stilts shifts outward to \\[ Q=D(P)=2,428-50 P \\] How would you now answer the questions posed in part (a)? c. Because stilt-making entrepreneurs are the cause of the upward-sloping long-run supply curve in this problem, they will receive all rents generated as industry output expands. Calculate the increase in rents between parts (a) and (b). Show that this value is identical to the change in long-run producer surplus as measured along the stilt supply curve.

The supply and demand model presented earlier in this chapter can be used to look at many other comparative statics questions. In this problem you are asked to explore three of them. In all of these, quantity demanded is given by \(D(P, \alpha)\) and quantity supplied by \(S(P, \beta)\) a. Shifts in supply: In Chapter 12 we analyzed the case of a shift in demand by looking at a comparative statics analysis of how changes in \(\alpha\) affect equilibrium price and quantity. For this problem you are to make a similar set of computations for a shift in a parameter of the supply function, \(\beta .\) That is, calculate \(d P^{*} / d \beta\) and \(d Q^{*} / d \beta .\) Be sure to calculate your results in both derivative and elasticity terms. Also describe with some simple graphs why the results here differ from those shown in the body of Chapter 12 b. \(\mathbf{A}\) quantity \(^{\text {- wed }}\) we" \(_{\pm}\) In our analysis of the imposition of a unit tax we showed how such a tax wedge can affect equilibrium price and quantity. A similar analysis can be done for a quantity "wedge" for which, in equilibrium, the quantity supplied may exceed the quantity demanded. Such a situation might arise, for example, if some portion of production were lost through spoilage or if some portion of production were demanded by the government as a payment for the right to do business. Formally, let \(\bar{Q}\) be the amount of the good lost. In this case equilibrium requires \(D(P)=Q\) and \(S(P)=Q+\bar{Q}\). Use the comparative statics methods developed in this chapter to calculate \(d P^{*} / d \bar{Q}\) and \(d Q^{*} / d \bar{Q} .\) [ In many cases it might be more reasonable to assume \(\bar{Q}=\delta Q\) (where \(\delta\) is a small decimal value). Without making any explicit calculations, how do you think this case would differ from the one you explicitly analyzed? c. The identification problem: An important issue in the empirical study of competitive markets is to decide whether observed price-quantity data points represent demand curves, supply curves, or some combination of the two. Explain the following conclusions using the comparative statics results we have obtained: I. If only the demand parameter \(\alpha\) takes on changing values, data on changing equilibrium values of price and quantity can be used to estimate the price elasticity of supply. ii. If only the supply parameter \(\beta\) takes on changing values, data on changing equilibrium values of price and quantity can be used to evaluate the price elasticity of supply (to answer this, you must have done part (a) of this problem). iii. If demand and supply curves are both only shifted by the same parameter [i.e., the demand and supply functions are \(D(P, \alpha) \text { and } S(P, \alpha)],\) neither of the price elasticities can be evaluated.

The development of optimal tax policy has been a major topic in public finance for centuries." Probably the most famous result in the theory of optimal taxation is due to the English economist Frank Ramsey, who conceptualized the problem as how to structure a tax system that would collect a given amount of revenues with the minimal deadweight loss." Specifically, suppose there are \(n\) goods \(\left(x_{i} \text { with prices } p_{i}\right)\) to be taxed with a sequence of ad valorem taxes (see Problem 12.10 ) whose rates are given by \(t_{i}(i=1, n)\). Therefore, total tax revenue is given by \(T=\Sigma_{l=1}^{l} t_{l} p_{i} x_{l}\). Ramsey's problem is for a fixed \(T\) to choose tax rates that will minimize total deadweight \(\operatorname{loss} D W=\Sigma_{j=1}^{m} D W\left(t_{i}\right)\) a. Use the Lagrange multiplier method to show that the solution to Ramsey's problem requires \(t_{i}=\lambda\left(1 / e_{s}-1 / e_{n}\right)\) where \(\lambda\), is the Lagrange multiplier for the tax constraint. b. Interpret the Ramsey result intuitively. c. Describe some shortcomings of the Ramsey approach to optimal taxation.

A perfectly competitive industry has a large number of potential entrants. Each firm has an identical cost structure such that long-run average cost is minimized at an output of 20 units \(\left(q_{i}=20\right) .\) The minimum average cost is \(\$ 10\) per unit. Total market demand is given by \\[ Q=D(P)=1,500-50 P \\] a. What is the industry's long-run supply schedule? b. What is the long-run equilibrium price \(\left(P^{*}\right) ?\) The total industry output \(\left(Q^{*}\right) ?\) The output of each firm \(\left(q^{*}\right) ?\) The number of firms? The profits of each firm? c. The short-run total cost function associated with each firm's long-run equilibrium output is given by \\[ C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+200 \\] Calculate the short-run average and marginal cost function. At what output level does short-run average cost reach a minimum? d. Calculate the short-run supply function for each firm and the industry short-run supply function. c. Suppose now that the market demand function shifts upward to \(Q=D(P)=2,000-50 P\). Using this new demand curve, answer part (b) for the very short run when firms cannot change their outputs. f. In the short run, use the industry short-run supply function to recalculate the answers to (b). g. What is the new long-run equilibrium for the industry?

Suppose that the demand function for a good has the linear form \(Q=D(P, I)=a+b P+c I\) and the supply function is also of the linear form \(Q=S(P)=d+g P\). a. Calculate equilibrium price and quantity for this market as a function of the parameters \(a, b, c, d,\) and \(g\) and of \(I\) (income), the exogenous shift term for the demand function. b, Use your results from part (a) to calculate the comparative statics derivative \(d P^{*} / d I\) c. Now calculate the same derivative using the comparative statics analysis of supply and demand presented in this chapter. You should be able to show that you get the same results in each case. d. Specify some assumed values for the various parameters of this problem and describe why the derivative \(d P^{*} / d I\) takes the form it does here.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free