Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

This problem concerns the relationship between demand and marginal revenue curves for a few functional forms. a. Show that, for a linear demand curve, the marginal revenue curve bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve for any price. b. Show that, for any linear demand curve, the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves is \(-1 / b \cdot q,\) where \(b(<0)\) is the slope of the demand curve. c. Show that, for a constant elasticity demand curve of the form \(q=a P^{b},\) the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves is a constant ratio of the height of the demand curve, with this constant depending on the price elasticity of demand. d. Show that, for any downward-sloping demand curve, the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves at any point can be found by using a linear approximation to the demand curve at that point and applying the procedure described in part (b). e. Graph the results of parts (a)-(d) of this problem.

Short Answer

Expert verified
#Question# Explain the relationship between demand and marginal revenue curves for different functional forms of demand, focusing on both linear and constant elasticity demand curves. #Answer# For linear demand curves, the relationship between the demand curve and the marginal revenue curve is such that the marginal revenue curve bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve for any price. The vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves at any price level can be represented by the formula: -1/b × q. In the case of constant elasticity demand curves, the marginal revenue curve is a downward-sloping curved line that is parallel to the demand curve, with a constant ratio between their heights. This ratio is equal to -b, where b is the elasticity of demand. For any downward-sloping demand curve, a linear approximation can be used to find the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves by calculating the tangent line to the demand curve at a specific point and applying the procedure for linear demand curves.

Step by step solution

01

Linear demand curve equation

Let the linear demand curve be given by the equation: \(q = a - b \cdot P\), where \(a\) and \(b\) are positive constants.
02

Finding marginal revenue

We know that the total revenue is equal to the product of price and quantity, or \(R(P) = P \cdot q = P \cdot (a - b \cdot P)\). To find the marginal revenue, we take the first derivative of the revenue function with respect to price: $$MR(P) = \frac{dR(P)}{dP} = a - 2 \cdot b \cdot P$$
03

Show that MR bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve

At any given price level, both demand and marginal revenue can be expressed as vertical distances from the horizontal axis. The vertical distance from the demand curve is given by \((a - b \cdot P) - 0 = a - b\cdot P\), and the vertical distance from the MR curve is given by \((a - 2 \cdot b \cdot P) - 0 = a - 2 \cdot b\cdot P\). Thus, the distance between demand and MR is \((\)a - b\cdot P) - (a - 2\cdot b\cdot P) = b\cdot P$. Since the distance between demand and MR at any given price is half the distance from the vertical axis \((2 \cdot b\cdot P),\) we can conclude that the marginal revenue curve bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve for any price. b. Vertical distance between demand and marginal revenue curves
04

Formula for vertical distance

As derived in part (a), the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curve at any price level is given by: \(-1/b \cdot q\). c. Constant elasticity demand curve
05

Constant elasticity demand curve equation

The constant elasticity demand curve is given by the equation: \(q = a \cdot P^{b}\).
06

Finding marginal revenue

The total revenue function is given by \(R(P) = P \cdot q = P \cdot (a \cdot P^{b})\). Taking the first derivative with respect to price, we get: $$MR(P) = a \cdot P^{b} + b \cdot a \cdot P^{b-1}$$
07

Proportional distance between demand and MR curves

The vertical distance between the demand and MR curves is given by \((a \cdot P^{b}) - (a \cdot P^{b} + b\cdot a\cdot P^{b-1}) = -b \cdot a \cdot P^{b-1}\). By dividing both sides by the demand function \((a \cdot P^{b})\), we find the constant ratio between the heights of the demand and MR curves: $$\frac{-b \cdot a \cdot P^{b-1}}{a \cdot P^{b}} = -b$$ d. Downward-sloping demand curve
08

Linear approximation of demand curve

To use the procedure from part (b) for any downward-sloping demand curve, we need to find a linear approximation of the demand curve at a given point. This can be done by calculating the tangent line to the demand curve at that point. Using the results from part (b), we can find the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves. e. Graphical representation
09

Graphing linear demand and MR curves

For a linear demand curve, draw a downward-sloping straight line representing the demand curve. The marginal revenue curve will be another downward-sloping straight line that is parallel to the demand curve and bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve for any price.
10

Graphing constant elasticity demand and MR curves

For a constant elasticity demand curve, draw a downward-sloping curved line representing the demand curve. The marginal revenue curve will be another downward-sloping curved line parallel to the demand curve and maintaining a constant ratio between their heights.
11

Graphing downward-sloping demand curve and linear approximation

For any downward-sloping demand curve, draw a downward-sloping curved line representing the demand curve. Use the tangent line to the demand curve at a particular point as a linear approximation of the demand curve. Then, apply the procedure from part (b) and draw the marginal revenue curve as a downward-sloping straight line parallel to the linear approximation.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Demand Curve
The demand curve is a fundamental concept in economics representing the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity of that good consumers are willing to purchase at various prices. It graphically shows the inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded, typically sloping downward from left to right. This downward slope indicates that, as the price decreases, the quantity demanded increases, and conversely, as the price increases, the quantity demanded decreases.

Understanding the demand curve is crucial because it provides insight into consumer preferences and the potential revenue a company can generate at different prices. It also serves as a basis for calculating other important economic measures, such as marginal revenue, which is vital for determining optimal pricing strategies for maximising profit.
Linear Demand Curve
A linear demand curve is a specific type of demand curve that shows a straight-line relationship between price and quantity demanded. It can be represented by the simple equation, \(q = a - b \times P\), where \(q\) is the quantity demanded, \(P\) is the price, \(a\) is the y-intercept indicating the maximum quantity demanded at a price of zero, and \(b\) is the slope, which shows the rate at which quantity demanded changes with price. The slope is normally negative, reflecting the inverse relationship between price and quantity.

The simplicity of the linear demand curve makes it a popular choice for basic economic analysis and helps in illustrating economic principles with clarity. Moreover, when analyzing marginal revenue in the context of a linear demand curve, marginal revenue will always be less than the price, as the curve for marginal revenue falls at twice the rate of the demand curve due to increased competition or decreased consumer willingness to pay as quantity increases.
Constant Elasticity Demand Curve
The constant elasticity demand curve represents a situation where the price elasticity of demand is the same at all points along the curve. Price elasticity measures how sensitive the quantity demanded is to a change in price. A constant elasticity demand curve is depicted by the equation \(q = a \times P^b\), where \(a\) and \(b\) are constants, and the elasticity is represented by the exponent \(b\).

This type of curve is nonlinear and reflects different market behaviors compared to linear demand curves. One key feature is that percentage changes in price lead to a constant percentage change in quantity demanded, regardless of the initial price level. When it comes to marginal revenue, for a product with constant price elasticity, the marginal revenue curve is a straight line with a constant slope reflecting the consistent elasticity.
Downward-Sloping Demand Curve
The downward-sloping demand curve, a universal concept in economics, illustrates that as the price of a product decreases, the quantity demanded increases, and as the price increases, demand falls. This behavior is due to the law of demand, which is based on the substitutability of goods, income effect, and diminishing marginal utility.

Real-world demand curves can take on many shapes but will generally slope downwards. They may not always be linear or exhibit constant elasticity. When estimating marginal revenue for such curves, economists often use a linear approximation at a particular point on the curve, just as an engineer might use a straight-line to approximate the slope of a curve at a particular point. This approximation simplifies the complex relationship between price and quantity demanded, highlighting the importance of understanding how various types of demand curves affect the analysis of marginal revenue and market dynamics.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

John's Lawn Mowing Service is a small business that acts as a price-taker (i.e., \(M R=P\) ). The prevailing market price of lawn mowing is \(\$ 20\) per acre. John's costs are given by \\[ \text { total cost }=0.1 q^{2}+10 q+50 \\] where \(q=\) the number of acres John chooses to cut a day. a. How many acres should John choose to cut to maximize profit? b. Calculate John's maximum daily profit. c. Graph these results, and label John's supply curve.

With a CES production function of the form \(q=\left(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho}\) a whole lot of algebra is needed to compute the profit function as \(\Pi(P, v, w)=K P^{1 /(1-\gamma)}\left(v^{1-\sigma}+w^{1-\sigma}\right)^{\gamma /(1-\sigma)(\gamma-1)}\) where \(\sigma=1 /(1-\rho)\) and \(K\) is a constant. a. If you are a glutton for punishment (or if your instructor is ), prove that the profit function takes this form. Perhaps the easiest way to do so is to start from the CES cost function in Example 10.2 b. Explain why this profit function provides a reasonable representation of a firm's behavior only for \(0<\gamma<1\) c. Explain the role of the elasticity of substitution \((\sigma)\) in this profit function. d. What is the supply function in this case? How does \(\sigma\) determine the extent to which that function shifts when input prices change? e. Derive the input demand functions in this case. How are these functions affected by the size of \(\sigma ?\)

The production function for a firm in the business of calculator assembly is given by \\[ q=2 \sqrt{l} \\] where \(q\) denotes finished calculator output and \(l\) denotes hours of labor input. The firm is a price-taker both for calculators (which sell for \(P\) ) and for workers (which can be hired at a wage rate of \(w\) per hour). a. What is the total cost function for this firm? b. What is the profit function for this firm? c. What is the supply function for assembled calculators \\[ [q(P, w)] ? \\] d. What is this firm's demand for labor function \([l(P, w)] ?\) e. Describe intuitively why these functions have the form they do.

How would you expect an increase in output price, \(P\), to affect the demand for capital and labor inputs? a. Explain graphically why, if neither input is inferior, it seems clear that a rise in \(P\) must not reduce the demand for either factor. b. Show that the graphical presumption from part (a) is demonstrated by the input demand functions that can be derived in the Cobb-Douglas case. c. Use the profit function to show how the presence of inferior inputs would lead to ambiguity in the effect of \(P\) on input demand.

Universal Widget produces high-quality widgets at its plant in Gulch, Nevada, for sale throughout the world. The cost function for total widget production \((q)\) is given by total cost \(=0.25 q^{2}\) Widgets are demanded only in Australia (where the demand curve is given by \(q_{A}=100-2 P_{A}\) and Lapland (where the demand curve is given by \(q_{L}=100-4 P_{L}\) ); thus, total demand equals \(q=q_{A}+q_{L}\). If Universal Widget can control the quantities supplied to cach market, how many should it sell in each location to maximize total profits? What price will be charged in each location?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free