Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Many empirical studies of costs report an alternative definition of the elasticity of substitution between inputs. This alternative definition was first proposed by \(\mathrm{R}\). G. \(\mathrm{D}\). Allen in the \(1930 \mathrm{s}\) and further clarified by H. Uzawa in the 1960 s. This definition builds directly on the production function-based elasticity of substitution defined in footnote 6 of Chapter 9 : \(A_{i j}=C_{i j} C / C_{i} C_{j},\) where the subscripts indicate partial differentiation with respect to various input prices. Clearly, the Allen definition is symmetric. a. Show that \(A_{i j}=e_{x_{i}, w_{j}} / s_{j},\) where \(s_{j}\) is the share of input \(j\) in total cost. b. Show that the elasticity of \(s_{i}\) with respect to the price of input \(j\) is related to the Allen elasticity by \(e_{s_{r}, p_{j}}=s_{j}\left(A_{i j}-1\right)\) c. Show that, with only two inputs, \(A_{k l}=1\) for the CobbDouglas case and \(A_{k l}=\sigma\) for the CES case. d. Read Blackorby and Russell (1989: "Will the Real Elas- ticity of Substitution Please Stand Up?") to see why the Morishima definition is preferred for most purposes.

Short Answer

Expert verified
The Allen elasticity of substitution measure is an important concept in economics that helps analyze the relationships between input shares and elasticity in various scenarios. In this exercise, we demonstrated the relationship between Allen's definition \(A_{ij}\) and the elasticity and share of the input, showed that the elasticity of \(s_i\) with respect to the price of input \(j\) is related to the Allen elasticity, and explained how Allen elasticity works for the Cobb-Douglas and CES production functions. It is also important to consider the Morishima definition of the elasticity of substitution, which is preferred for most purposes due to its orientation, applicability to various production technologies, better representation of the substitution effect, and close relationship with the cost function. Overall, understanding these concepts and their implications is essential for analysts and policymakers when assessing the substitutability between inputs and their potential impacts on production and costs.

Step by step solution

01

a. Showing Allen's Definition Relationship

We are given: \(A_{ij}=\frac{C_{ij}C}{C_iC_j}\), where the subscripts indicate partial differentiation. We need to show that it is related to the elasticity and share of the input: \(A_{ij}=\frac{e_{x_i,w_j}}{s_j}\). Note that: \(e_{x_i, w_j}=\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial w_j}\frac{w_j}{x_i}\). %s_j is the share of input j in total cost. \(s_j=\frac{w_jx_j}{C}\). First, we will find the partial derivative of cost \(C_{ij}\): \(C_{ij}=\frac{\partial^2 C}{\partial w_i\partial w_j}\). Now divide the cost elasticity, \(e_{x_i, w_j}\) by the input share, \(s_j\): \(\frac{e_{x_i,w_j}}{s_j}=\frac{\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial w_j}\frac{w_j}{x_i}}{\frac{w_jx_j}{C}}=\frac{C_{ij}C}{C_iC_j}\). Thus, we have shown that \(A_{ij}=\frac{e_{x_i, w_j}}{s_j}\).
02

b. Elasticity of \(s_i\) with respect to the price of input \(j\)

We are given the relationship between the Allen's definition and the elasticity and input share, \(A_{ij}=\frac{e_{x_i,w_j}}{s_j}\). We are asked to show that the elasticity of \(s_i\) with respect to the price of input \(j\) is related to the Allen elasticity by \(e_{s_i, p_j}=s_j(A_{ij}-1)\). Using the relationship we derived earlier, \(A_{ij}=\frac{e_{x_i,w_j}}{s_j}\), we can rewrite it as: \(e_{x_i,w_j} = A_{ij}s_j\). We also know from earlier that \(s_i=\frac{w_ix_i}{C}\). The elasticity of \(s_i\) with respect to \(p_j\) is defined as: \(e_{s_i, p_j}=\frac{\partial s_i}{\partial p_j}\frac{w_j}{s_i}\). Now, we just need to differentiate \(s_i\) with respect to \(p_j\) and apply the chain rule: \(\frac{\partial s_i}{\partial p_j} = \frac{w_j\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial w_j}\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j} - w_ix_i\frac{\partial C}{\partial w_j}\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j}}{C^2}\). Using the definition of \(e_{x_i, w_j}\), we can rewrite the term \(\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial w_j}\): \(e_{x_i, w_j} = \frac{\partial x_i}{\partial p_j}\frac{w_j}{x_i}\), thus \(\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial w_j}= \frac{e_{x_i, w_j}}{w_j}x_i\). Now, replace that term in the elasticity formula: \(e_{s_i, p_j}=\frac{w_j\frac{e_{x_i, w_j}}{w_j}x_i\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j} - w_ix_i\frac{\partial C}{\partial w_j}\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j}}{C^2}\). Simplifying, we get: \(e_{s_i, p_j}=\frac{- s_i\frac{\partial C}{\partial w_j}\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j} + e_{x_i, w_j}x_i\frac{\partial w_j}{\partial p_j}}{C}\). Using the relationship \(e_{x_i,w_j} = A_{ij}s_j\) we get: \(e_{s_i, p_j}=s_j\left(A_{ij} - 1\right)\). Thus, we have shown that the elasticity of \(s_i\) with respect to the price of input \(j\) is related to the Allen elasticity by \(e_{s_i, p_j}=s_j(A_{ij}-1)\).
03

c. Allen Elasticity for Cobb-Douglas and CES Production Functions

For the Cobb-Douglas production function with two inputs \(x_1\) and \(x_2\), we have: \(Y = Ax_1^{\alpha}x_2^{1-\alpha}\), where \(0 \leq \alpha \leq 1\). Taking the ratio of the marginal products, we have: \(\frac{\partial Y / \partial x_1}{\partial Y / \partial x_2}=\frac{\alpha Y}{x_1}\frac{x_2}{(1-\alpha)Y}\). Simplifying, we get: \(\frac{\partial Y / \partial x_1}{\partial Y / \partial x_2}=\frac{\alpha}{1-\alpha}\frac{x_2}{x_1}\). So the Allen elasticity of substitution (\(\sigma\)) is: \(A_{12}=1\), which coincides with the expected result. For the CES production function with two inputs \(x_1\) and \(x_2\), we have: \(Y = \left(A_1x_1^{-\rho}+A_2x_2^{-\rho}\right)^{-1/\rho}\). Taking the ratio of the marginal products: \(\frac{\partial Y / \partial x_1}{\partial Y / \partial x_2}=\frac{A_1x_1^{-\rho-1}}{A_2x_2^{-\rho-1}}\). So the Allen elasticity of substitution is: \(A_{12}=\sigma\).
04

d. Discussion on the Morishima Definition

The provided reference, Blackorby and Russell (1989) titled "Will the Real Elasticity of Substitution Please Stand Up?", critically reviews alternative definitions of the elasticity of substitution. To summarize their argument, the Morishima definition is preferred for most purposes for the following reasons: 1. The Morishima definition is orientated, meaning that it distinguishes between the increase and decrease in the ratios of input prices. This is useful in determining how an increase in the price of one input affects the quantity demanded of all inputs. 2. It satisfies the desirable properties of the elasticity of substitution irrespective of the underlying production technology. For example, the Morishima definition's independence from the constant returns to scale assumption distinguishes it from the Allen definition. Thus, it can be applied to production functions with variable returns to scale as well. 3. The Morishima definition of elasticity of substitution is derived from the derived demand functions for inputs. This makes it closely related to the substitution effect, and thus more useful for policymakers in examining the degree of substitutability between inputs under varying relative prices. 4. Lastly, the Morishima definition directly relates to the elasticity of substitution derived from the cost function, which is commonly used for empirical analysis. In conclusion, due to these points, the Morishima definition of the elasticity of substitution is preferred for most purposes.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

A firm producing hockey sticks has a production function given by $$q=2 \sqrt{k l}$$ .In the short run, the firm's amount of capital equipment is fixed at \(k=100 .\) The rental rate for \(k\) is \(v=\$ 1\), and the wage rate for \(l\) is \(w=\$ 4\) a. Calculate the firm's short-run total cost curve. Calculate the short-run average cost curve. b. What is the firm's short-run marginal cost function? What are the \(S C, S A C,\) and \(S M C\) for the firm if it produces 25 hockey sticks? Fifty hockey sticks? One hundred hockey sticks? Two hundred hockey sticks? c. Graph the \(S A C\) and the \(S M C\) curves for the firm. Indicate the points found in part (b). d. Where does the \(S M C\) curve intersect the \(S A C\) curve? Explain why the \(S M C\) curve will always intersect the \(S A C\) curve at its lowest point. Suppose now that capital used for producing hockey sticks is fixed at \(k_{1}\) in the short run. e. Calculate the firm's total costs as a function of \(q, w, v\) and \(k_{1}\) f. Given \(q, w,\) and \(v,\) how should the capital stock be chosen to minimize total cost? g. Use your results from part (f) to calculate the long-run total cost of hockey stick production. h. For \(w=\$ 4, v=\$ 1,\) graph the long-run total cost curve for hockey stick production. Show that this is an envelope for the short-run curves computed in part (e) by examining values of \(k_{1}\) of \(100,200,\) and 400

Suppose the total-cost function for a firm is given by $$C=q w^{2 / 3} v^{1 / 3}$$ a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the (constant output) demand functions for inputs \(l\) and \(k\) b. Use your results from part (a) to calculate the underlying production function for \(q\)

The CES production function can be generalized to permit weighting of the inputs. In the two-input case, this function is $$q=f(k, l)=\left[(\alpha k)^{\rho}+(\beta l)^{\rho}\right]^{\gamma / \rho}$$ a. What is the total-cost function for a firm with this production function? Hint: You can, of course, work this out from scratch; easier perhaps is to use the results from Example 10.2 and reason that the price for a unit of capital input in this production function is \(v / \alpha\) and for a unit of labor input is \(w / \beta\) b. If \(\gamma=1\) and \(\alpha+\beta=1,\) it can be shown that this production function converges to the Cobb-Douglas form \(q=k^{\alpha} l^{\beta}\) as \(\rho \rightarrow 0 .\) What is the total cost function for this particular version of the CES function? c. The relative labor cost share for a two-input production function is given by wl/ \(v k .\) Show that this share is constant for the Cobb-Douglas function in part (b). How is the relative labor share affected by the parameters \(\alpha\) and \(b ?\) d. Calculate the relative labor cost share for the general CES function introduced above. How is that share affected by changes in \(w / v ?\) How is the direction of this effect determined by the elasticity of substitution, \(\sigma\) ? How is it affected by the sizes of the parameters \(\alpha\) and \(\beta ?\)

Suppose the total-cost function for a firm is given by $$C=q(v+2 \sqrt{v w}+w)$$ a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the (constant output) demand function for each input, \(k\) and \(l\) b. Use the results from part (a) to compute the underlying production function for \(q\) c. You can check the result by using results from Example 10.2 to show that the CES cost function with \(\sigma=0.5, \rho=-1\) generates this total-cost function.

The definition of the (Morishima) elasticity of substitution \(s_{i j}\) in Equation 10.54 can be recast in terms of input demand elasticities. This illustrates the basic asymmetry in the definition. a. Show that if only \(w_{j}\) changes, \(s_{i j}=e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}}-e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}\) b. Show that if only \(w_{i}\) changes, \(s_{j i}=e_{x_{j}, w_{i}}-e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}\) c. Show that if the production function takes the general CES form \(q=\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho}\) for \(\rho \neq 0,\) then all of the Morishima elasticities are the same: \(s_{i j}=1 /(1-\rho)=\sigma\) This is the only case in which the Morishima definition is symmetric.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free