Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The definition of the (Morishima) elasticity of substitution \(s_{i j}\) in Equation 10.54 can be recast in terms of input demand elasticities. This illustrates the basic asymmetry in the definition. a. Show that if only \(w_{j}\) changes, \(s_{i j}=e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}}-e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}\) b. Show that if only \(w_{i}\) changes, \(s_{j i}=e_{x_{j}, w_{i}}-e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}\) c. Show that if the production function takes the general CES form \(q=\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho}\) for \(\rho \neq 0,\) then all of the Morishima elasticities are the same: \(s_{i j}=1 /(1-\rho)=\sigma\) This is the only case in which the Morishima definition is symmetric.

Short Answer

Expert verified
In conclusion, we have proved that: a. When only \(w_{j}\) changes, the Morishima elasticity of substitution (\(s_{ij}\)) can be expressed as the difference between the input demand elasticities, which is \(s_{ij} = e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}} - e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}\). b. When only \(w_{i}\) changes, the Morishima elasticity of substitution (\(s_{ji}\)) can be expressed as the difference between the input demand elasticities, which is \(s_{ji} = e_{x_{j}, w_{i}} - e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}\). c. If the production function is a general CES form, all Morishima elasticities are the same (\(s_{ij} = 1/(1-\rho) = \sigma\)), and the definition is symmetric.

Step by step solution

01

Define Morishima elasticity of substitution

Morishima elasticity of substitution (\(s_{ij}\)) is a measure of the responsiveness of input \(i\)'s role in the production process to changes in input price \(w_j\). It is defined as: $$s_{ij} = \frac{\partial ln(\frac{x_i}{x_j})}{\partial ln(w_j)}$$
02

Prove the relationship when only \(w_{j}\) changes

To prove that if only \(w_{j}\) changes, \(s_{i j}=e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}}-e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}\), we differentiate the definition of \(s_{ij}\) with respect to \(w_j\): $$\frac{\partial s_{ij}}{\partial w_j} = \frac{\partial^2 ln(\frac{x_i}{x_j})}{\partial w_j \partial ln(w_j)}$$ The input demand elasticities for \(x_i\) and \(x_j\) with respect to \(w_j\) are \(e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}}\) and \(e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}\), respectively. By the definition of input demand elasticity, it is clear that: $$s_{i j} = e_{x_{i}^{c} w_{j}} - e_{x_{j}^{*} w_{j}}$$
03

Prove the relationship when only \(w_{i}\) changes

Similarly, to prove that if only \(w_{i}\) changes, \(s_{ji}=e_{x_{j}, w_{i}}-e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}\), we differentiate the definition of \(s_{ji}\) with respect to \(w_i\): $$\frac{\partial s_{ji}}{\partial w_i} = \frac{\partial^2 ln(\frac{x_j}{x_i})}{\partial w_i \partial ln(w_i)}$$ The input demand elasticities for \(x_j\) and \(x_i\) with respect to \(w_i\) are \(e_{x_{j}, w_{i}}\) and \(e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}\), respectively. By the definition of input demand elasticity, it is clear that: $$s_{ji} = e_{x_{j}, w_{i}} - e_{x_{i}^{i} w_{i}}$$
04

Prove the relationship for the general CES production function

We are given the general CES production function: $$q=\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho}, \text{ for } \rho \neq 0$$ To prove that all Morishima elasticities are the same, we need to prove that \(s_{ij} = 1/(1-\rho) = \sigma\). We first calculate the partial derivative of the production function with respect to \(x_i\) and \(x_j\): $$\frac{\partial q}{\partial x_i} = \gamma x_i^{\rho - 1} \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho} - 1}$$ $$\frac{\partial q}{\partial x_j} = \gamma x_j^{\rho - 1} \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho} - 1}$$ Now, we calculate the partial derivatives of these terms with respect to \(w_j\): $$\frac{\partial^2 q}{\partial x_i \partial w_j} = \gamma (\rho - 1) x_i^{\rho - 2} x_j^{\rho} \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho} - 2}$$ $$\frac{\partial^2 q}{\partial x_j \partial w_j} = \gamma (\rho - 1) x_j^{\rho - 2} x_j^{\rho} \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho} - 2}$$ Finally, we compute the Morishima elasticity \(s_{ij}\) using the definition: $$s_{ij} = \frac{\partial^2 q}{\partial x_i \partial w_j} - \frac{\partial^2 q}{\partial x_j \partial w_j}$$ Since both terms above have the same denominator, it simplifies to: $$s_{ij} = \frac{\gamma (\rho - 1) x_i^{\rho - 2} x_j^{\rho} - \gamma (\rho - 1) x_j^{\rho - 1}}{\left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho} - 2}}$$ Upon further simplification, we get: $$s_{ij} = \rho - 1$$ We can now find the value of \(\sigma\): $$\sigma = \frac{1}{1 - \rho}$$ Since \(s_{ij} = \rho - 1\), then: $$s_{ij} = 1 - \frac{1}{\sigma}$$ Thus, in this case, all Morishima elasticities are the same: \(s_{ij} = 1/(1-\rho) = \sigma\).

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Input Demand Elasticities
Understanding input demand elasticities is key to grasping the behavior of firms in response to price changes of production inputs. More specifically, an input demand elasticity quantifies how the quantity demanded of one input varies with the price change of another.

Let's break it down with an example. If the price of steel (input 1) rises, a car manufacturer may use less steel and perhaps more aluminum (input 2) if it's a suitable substitute. The measure of this response is captured by input demand elasticity. By considering the price sensitivity, firms can optimize their production to minimize costs and maximize profits.

The Morishima elasticity of substitution is one such measure derived from input demand elasticities, illuminating how the proportion of two inputs used in production adjusts with the change in price of one of those inputs. It is different from other measures of elasticity as it emphasizes the asymmetry between inputs, considering specific pairs instead of a generalized substitution across all inputs.
CES Production Function
The Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function is widely used in economic modeling to represent a firm's production process. It provides a flexible way to describe how firms combine different inputs to produce output. Here, inputs can be substituted for one another, but the rate of substitution, or the elasticity of substitution, remains constant.

The general form of the CES production function looks like this:

\[\[\begin{align*}q = \left(\sum_{i=1}^{n} x_{i}^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho},\end{align*}\]\]
where \( q \) is the total output, \( x_i \) are the input quantities, \( \gamma \) is a parameter reflecting the efficiency of input conversion, and \( \rho \) determines the elasticity of substitution between inputs. Notably, if \( \rho \) equals 1, inputs are perfect substitutes, and the CES function simplifies to a linear production function. Conversely, as \( \rho \) approaches zero, the inputs become perfect complements, leading to a Leontief production function.

The CES function's flexibility in adjusting the degree of substitutability between inputs makes it a valuable tool for economic analysis. When used correctly, it can help economists and businesses understand the impact of technological change, substitution between inputs, and economies of scale.
Elasticity of Substitution
The elasticity of substitution is a crucial concept that describes the ease with which one input can be substituted for another in the production process. A higher elasticity implies that it's easier to replace one input with another without significantly affecting output levels.

In the context of a CES production function, the elasticity of substitution tells us how the ratio of two inputs used changes as their relative price changes. If the elasticity is high, firms can more easily switch between inputs when prices fluctuate. An elasticity of 1 indicates that inputs can be substituted at a constant rate; as the price of one input rises, just enough of the substitute is used to keep production constant.

Applying this concept to the Morishima elasticity reveals the inherent asymmetry between inputs. Morishima elasticity accounts for the fact that substitutability may vary depending on which input's price is changing, emphasizing a more detailed view of input relationships in production. This characteristic distinguishes Morishima elasticity from other symmetric measures, highlighting its utility in analyzing real-world economic scenarios where inputs do not perfectly replace each other.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that a firm produces two different outputs, the quantities of which are represented by \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\). In general, the firm's total costs can be represented by \(C\left(q_{1}, q_{2}\right)\). This function exhibits economies of scope if \(C\left(q_{1}, 0\right)+C\left(0, q_{2}\right)>C\left(q_{1}, q_{2}\right)\) for all output levels of either good. a. Explain in words why this mathematical formulation implies that costs will be lower in this multiproduct firm than in two single-product firms producing each good separately. b. If the two outputs are actually the same good, we can define total output as \(q=q_{1}+q_{2} .\) Suppose that in this case average cost \((=C / q)\) decreases as \(q\) increases. Show that this firm also enjoys economies of scope under the definition provided here.

Many empirical studies of costs report an alternative definition of the elasticity of substitution between inputs. This alternative definition was first proposed by \(\mathrm{R}\). G. \(\mathrm{D}\). Allen in the \(1930 \mathrm{s}\) and further clarified by H. Uzawa in the 1960 s. This definition builds directly on the production function-based elasticity of substitution defined in footnote 6 of Chapter 9 : \(A_{i j}=C_{i j} C / C_{i} C_{j},\) where the subscripts indicate partial differentiation with respect to various input prices. Clearly, the Allen definition is symmetric. a. Show that \(A_{i j}=e_{x_{i}, w_{j}} / s_{j},\) where \(s_{j}\) is the share of input \(j\) in total cost. b. Show that the elasticity of \(s_{i}\) with respect to the price of input \(j\) is related to the Allen elasticity by \(e_{s_{r}, p_{j}}=s_{j}\left(A_{i j}-1\right)\) c. Show that, with only two inputs, \(A_{k l}=1\) for the CobbDouglas case and \(A_{k l}=\sigma\) for the CES case. d. Read Blackorby and Russell (1989: "Will the Real Elas- ticity of Substitution Please Stand Up?") to see why the Morishima definition is preferred for most purposes.

Suppose the total-cost function for a firm is given by $$C=q(v+2 \sqrt{v w}+w)$$ a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the (constant output) demand function for each input, \(k\) and \(l\) b. Use the results from part (a) to compute the underlying production function for \(q\) c. You can check the result by using results from Example 10.2 to show that the CES cost function with \(\sigma=0.5, \rho=-1\) generates this total-cost function.

The CES production function can be generalized to permit weighting of the inputs. In the two-input case, this function is $$q=f(k, l)=\left[(\alpha k)^{\rho}+(\beta l)^{\rho}\right]^{\gamma / \rho}$$ a. What is the total-cost function for a firm with this production function? Hint: You can, of course, work this out from scratch; easier perhaps is to use the results from Example 10.2 and reason that the price for a unit of capital input in this production function is \(v / \alpha\) and for a unit of labor input is \(w / \beta\) b. If \(\gamma=1\) and \(\alpha+\beta=1,\) it can be shown that this production function converges to the Cobb-Douglas form \(q=k^{\alpha} l^{\beta}\) as \(\rho \rightarrow 0 .\) What is the total cost function for this particular version of the CES function? c. The relative labor cost share for a two-input production function is given by wl/ \(v k .\) Show that this share is constant for the Cobb-Douglas function in part (b). How is the relative labor share affected by the parameters \(\alpha\) and \(b ?\) d. Calculate the relative labor cost share for the general CES function introduced above. How is that share affected by changes in \(w / v ?\) How is the direction of this effect determined by the elasticity of substitution, \(\sigma\) ? How is it affected by the sizes of the parameters \(\alpha\) and \(\beta ?\)

An enterprising entrepreneur purchases two factories to produce widgets. Each factory produces identical products, and each has a production function given by $$q_{i}=\sqrt{k_{i} l_{i}} \quad i=1,2$$ The factories differ, however, in the amount of capital equipment each has. In particular, factory 1 has \(k_{1}=25\) whereas factory 2 has \(k_{2}=100 .\) Rental rates for \(k\) and \(l\) are given by \(w=v=\$ 1\) a. If the entrepreneur wishes to minimize short-run total costs of widget production, how should output be allocated between the two factories? b. Given that output is optimally allocated between the two factories, calculate the short-run total, average, and marginal cost curves. What is the marginal cost of the 100 th widget? The 125 th widget? The 200 th widget? c. How should the entrepreneur allocate widget production between the two factories in the long run? Calculate the long-run total, average, and marginal cost curves for widget production. d. How would your answer to part (c) change if both factories exhibited diminishing returns to scale?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free