Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Show that Euler's theorem implies that, for a constant returns-to-scale production function \([q=f(k, l)]\) $$q=f_{k} \cdot k+f_{l} \cdot l$$ Use this result to show that, for such a production function, if \(M P_{l}>A P_{l}\) then \(M P_{k}\) must be negative. What does this imply about where production must take place? Can a firm ever produce at a point where \(A P_{l}\) is increasing?

Short Answer

Expert verified
Explain your answer. Answer: No, a firm can never produce at a point where the average product of labor is increasing. This is because an increasing average product of labor implies that the marginal product of labor is greater than the average product. As shown in the solution, at such points, the marginal product of capital would be negative, implying that adding more capital to the production process would reduce the total output. Firms would not choose to produce at such levels, as it would be inefficient and lead to wastage of resources.

Step by step solution

01

Write down Euler's theorem for homogeneous functions

Euler's theorem states that for a homogeneous function of degree \(n\), say \(F(x,y)\), the following holds: $$n \times F(x,y) = x \cdot \frac{\partial F(x,y)}{\partial x} + y \cdot \frac{\partial F(x,y)}{\partial y}$$
02

Apply Euler's theorem to the production function

Since the production function \(q=f(k,l)\) exhibits constant returns to scale (CRS), it is a homogeneous function of degree 1 (\(n=1\)). Thus, applying Euler's theorem, we get: $$q=f(k,l) = k \cdot \frac{\partial f(k,l)}{\partial k} + l \cdot \frac{\partial f(k,l)}{\partial l}$$ Which can also be written as: $$q= f_k \cdot k + f_l \cdot l$$
03

Analyze the relationship between MPL, APL, and MPK

We are given that the marginal product of labor (MPL) is greater than the average product of labor (APL): \(MP_l > AP_l\). We need to show that in this case, the marginal product of capital (\(MP_k\)) must be negative. Since \(AP_l = \frac{q}{l}\), we have \(MP_l > \frac{q}{l}\). Multiplying both sides by \(l\), we get: $$MP_l \cdot l > q$$ Using our derived equation from Euler's theorem, we can rewrite this inequality as: $$MP_l \cdot l > f_k \cdot k + f_l \cdot l$$ Now, we can rearrange the inequality to isolate \(MP_k = f_k\) on one side: $$f_k \cdot k < - (MP_l - f_l) \cdot l$$ Since \(l > 0\), we can conclude that: $$MP_k = f_k < 0$$ This means that the marginal product of capital must be negative if the marginal product of labor is greater than the average product of labor.
04

Discuss the implications of these results for production decisions

The results imply that if the firm produces at a point where the marginal product of labor is greater than the average product of labor, it must have a negative marginal product of capital. This means that at such a point, adding more capital to the production process would actually reduce the total production. Firms would not want to produce at such a level, as it would be inefficient and lead to wastage of resources. As for the question whether a firm can ever produce at a point where the average product of labor is increasing, the answer is no. An increasing average product of labor implies that the marginal product of labor is greater than the average product. As we have shown, at such points the marginal product of capital would be negative, and therefore, firms would not choose to produce at such levels.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Constant Returns to Scale
A production function with constant returns to scale (CRS) means that if you multiply all inputs by a certain factor, the output will be multiplied by the same factor too. For instance, doubling both labor and capital will double the output.
This property can be formally captured by homogeneous functions of degree 1. CRS is important in economics because it suggests that the size of the firm doesn't affect its efficiency.
Such functions maintain proportionality, ensuring that expanding production doesn't inherently increase or decrease average costs. Euler's theorem is often used to prove properties of CRS, demonstrating how output is distributed among inputs. This balance in scaling assures predictability and stability in production processes.
Marginal Product of Labor
The marginal product of labor (MPL) is the additional amount of output produced when one more unit of labor is added, keeping other inputs constant. To find MPL mathematically, you take the derivative of the production function with respect to labor.
  • MPL = \(\frac{\partial f(k,l)}{\partial l}\)
Understanding MPL helps businesses decide how much labor to employ. If MPL is greater than the wage rate, the company benefits by hiring more labor. However, as more workers are added, MPL usually decreases because less capital and resources are available per worker—this is known as diminishing marginal returns.
Average Product of Labor
The average product of labor (APL) represents the output produced on average per unit of labor. It is calculated by dividing the total output by the number of labor units used. It acts as a measure of productivity and indicates how well resources are utilized.
  • APL = \(\frac{q}{l}\)
Comparing APL with MPL can provide insights into productivity trends. If MPL is greater than APL, then APL is increasing, suggesting potential efficiency gains. However, if MPL drops below APL, adding more workers reduces efficiency, indicating an overuse of labor relative to other inputs.
Marginal Product of Capital
The marginal product of capital (MPK) describes the additional output obtained from increasing the capital input by one unit, while holding labor constant. It is computed as the derivative of the production function with respect to capital.
  • MPK = \(\frac{\partial f(k,l)}{\partial k}\)
Understanding MPK is crucial for firms when deciding on investments in capital. Like MPL, MPK also typically exhibits diminishing returns, meaning each additional unit of capital contributes less to output than the previous one.
In the context of Euler's theorem, negative MPK indicates that further increases in capital can actually decrease total output, guiding firms in their capital allocation decisions.
Homogeneous Functions
Homogeneous functions play an essential role in understanding economic principles like constant returns to scale. A function is homogeneous of degree \(n\) if, when all inputs are scaled by a constant \(t\), the output scales by \(t^n\). For CRS, this degree is typically 1, as output scales directly with inputs.
Homogeneous functions allow economists to use Euler's theorem to decompose the contributions of different inputs. For instance:
  • If a production function is homogeneous of degree 1, the function can always be expressed as a sum of its partial derivatives, multiplied by their respective inputs, emphasizing the output's reliance on each input's combined effect.
Recognizing a function's homogeneity aids in predicting how shifts in resources affect productivity and helps in formulating efficient resource allocation strategies.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

As we have seen in many places, the general Cobb-Douglas production function for two inputs is given by $$q=f(k, l)=A k^{\alpha} l^{\beta}$$ where \(0<\alpha<1\) and \(0<\beta<1 .\) For this production function: a. Show that \(f_{k}>0, f_{1}>0, f_{k k}<0, f_{l l}<0,\) and \(f_{k l}=f_{l k}>0\) b. Show that \(e_{q, k}=\alpha\) and \(e_{q, l}=\beta\) c. In footnote \(5,\) we defined the scale elasticity as$$e_{q, t}=\frac{\partial f(t k, t l)}{\partial t} \cdot \frac{t}{f(t k, t l)}$$ where the expression is to be evaluated at \(t=1 .\) Show that, for this Cobb-Douglas function, \(e_{q, t}=\alpha+\beta .\) Hence in this case the scale elasticity and the returns to scale of the production function agree (for more on this concept see Problem 9.9 ). d. Show that this function is quasi-concave. e. Show that the function is concave for \(\alpha+\beta \leq 1\) but not concave for \(\alpha+\beta>1\)

Sam Malone is considering renovating the bar stools at Cheers. The production function for new bar stools is given by $$q=0.1 k^{0.2} l^{0.8}$$ where \(q\) is the number of bar stools produced during the renovation week, \(k\) represents the number of hours of bar stool lathes used during the week, and \(l\) represents the number of worker hours employed during the period. Sam would like to provide 10 new bar stools, and he has allocated a budget of \(\$ 10,000\) for the project. a. Sam reasons that because bar stool lathes and skilled bar stool workers both cost the same amount ( \(\$ 50\) per hour), he might as well hire these two inputs in equal amounts. If Sam proceeds in this way, how much of each input will he hire and how much will the renovation project cost? b. Norm (who knows something about bar stools) argues that once again Sam has forgotten his microeconomics. He asserts that Sam should choose quantities of inputs so that their marginal (not average) productivities are equal. If Sam opts for this plan instead, how much of each input will he hire and how much will the renovation project cost? c. On hearing that Norm's plan will save money, Cliff argues that Sam should put the savings into more bar stools to provide seating for more of his USPS colleagues. How many more bar stools can Sam get for his budget if he follows Cliff's plan? d. Carla worries that Cliff's suggestion will just mean more work for her in delivering food to bar patrons. How might she convince Sam to stick to his original 10 -bar stool plan?

Power Goat Lawn Company uses two sizes of mowers to cut lawns. The smaller mowers have a 22 -inch deck. The larger ones combine two of the 22 -inch decks in a single mower. For each size of mower, Power Goat has a different production function, given by the rows of the following table. $$\begin{array}{lccc} \hline & \begin{array}{c} \text { Output per Hour } \\ \text { (square feet) } \end{array} & \begin{array}{c} \text { Capital Input } \\ \text { (# of 22" mowers) } \end{array} & \text { Labor Input } \\ \hline \text { Small mowers } & 5000 & 1 & 1 \\ \text { Large mowers } & 8000 & 2 & 1 \\ \hline \end{array}$$ a. Graph the \(q=40,000\) square feet isoquant for the first production function. How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used if these factors were combined without waste? b. Answer part (a) for the second function. c. How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used without waste if half of the 40,000 -square-foot lawn were cut by the method of the first production function and half by the method of the second? How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used if one fourth of the lawn were cut by the first method and three fourths by the second? What does it mean to speak of fractions of \(k\) and \(l\) ? d. Based on your observations in part (c), draw a \(q=40,000\) isoquant for the combined production functions.

Consider a generalization of the production function in Example 9.3: $$q=\beta_{0}+\beta_{1} \sqrt{k l}+\beta_{2} k+\beta_{3} l$$ $$0 \leq \beta_{i} \leq 1, \quad i=0, \dots, 3$$ a. If this function is to exhibit constant returns to scale, what restrictions should be placed on the parameters \(\beta_{0}, \ldots, \beta_{3} ?\) b. Show that, in the constant returns-to-scale case, this function exhibits diminishing marginal productivities and that the marginal productivity functions are homogeneous of degree 0 c. Calculate \(\sigma\) in this case. Although \(\sigma\) is not in general constant, for what values of the \(\beta\) 's does \(\sigma=0,1\), or \(\infty ?\)

Suppose that the production of crayons \((q)\) is conducted at two locations and uses only labor as an input. The production function in location 1 is given by \(q_{1}=10 l_{1}^{0.5}\) and in location 2 by \(q_{2}=50 l_{2}^{0.5}\) a. If a single firm produces crayons in both locations, then it will obviously want to get as large an output as possible given the labor input it uses. How should it allocate labor between the locations to do so? Explain precisely the relationship between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\) b. Assuming that the firm operates in the efficient manner described in part (a), how does total output ( \(q\) ) depend on the total amount of labor hired \((l) ?\)

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free