Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose we are given the constant returns-to-scale CES production function \[ q=\left(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho}\right)^{1 / \rho} \] a. Show that MPk=(q/k)1ρ and MPl=(q/l)1ρ b. Show that RTS=(k/l)1ρ; use this to show that \[ \sigma=1 /(1-\rho) \] c. Determine the output elasticities for k and l; and show that their sum equals 1 d. Prove that \[ \frac{q}{l}=\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} \] and hence that \[ \ln \left(\frac{q}{l}\right)=\sigma \ln \left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right) \] Note: The latter equality is useful in empirical work because we may approximate q/l by the competitively determined wage rate. Hence σ can be estimated from a regression of ln(q/I) on lnw.

Short Answer

Expert verified
a. The marginal products of capital and labor, denoted by MPk and MPl, are found by taking the partial derivatives of the CES production function. The expressions for the marginal products are: \[ MP_{k} = (q / k)^{1 - \rho} \] and \[ MP_{l} = (q / l)^{1 - \rho} \] b. The relationship between RTS and elasticity of substitution, denoted by σ, is given by: \[ \sigma = 1 / (1 - \rho) \] c. The output elasticities of capital and labor, denoted by Ek and El, are found to be: \[ E_{k} = \rho \] and \[ E_{l} = \rho \] It is also shown that their sum equals 1: \[ E_{k} + E_{l} = 1 \] d. The given relationship between output and marginal product is proven to be: \[ \frac{q}{l}=\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} \] and the logarithmic form of the relationship is shown as: \[ \ln \left(\frac{q}{l}\right)=\sigma \ln\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right) \]

Step by step solution

01

a. Find the marginal products of capital and labor.

To find the marginal products of capital and labor, we need to take the partial derivatives of the CES production function with respect to k and l respectively. The CES production function is given by: \[ q=\left(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho}\right)^{1 / \rho} \] Differentiating with respect to k, we get: \[ \frac{\partial q}{\partial k}=\frac{1}{\rho}(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho})^{\frac{1}{\rho}-1}k^{\rho-1} \] Now, divide by k: \[ M P_{k} = \frac{\partial q}{\partial k}\frac{1}{k} = \frac{1}{\rho}(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho})^{\frac{1}{\rho}-1}\frac{k^{\rho-1}}{k} \] We find that: \[ M P_{k} = (q / k)^{1 - \rho} \] Similarly, differentiating with respect to l, we get: \[ \frac{\partial q}{\partial l}=\frac{1}{\rho}(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho})^{\frac{1}{\rho}-1}l^{\rho-1} \] Now, divide by l: \[ M P_{l} = \frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\frac{1}{l} = \frac{1}{\rho}(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho})^{\frac{1}{\rho}-1}\frac{l^{\rho-1}}{l} \] We find that: \[ M P_{l} = (q / l)^{1 - \rho} \]
02

b. Show the relationship between RTS and elasticity of substitution.

Recall that the expression for RTS can be derived from the ratio of marginal products, which is given by: \[ R T S = \frac{M P_{k}}{M P_{l}} \] Using the expressions for MPk and MPl we found in part (a): \[ R T S = \frac{(q / k)^{1 - \rho}}{(q / l)^{1 - \rho}} \] Simplifying, we get: \[ R T S = (k / l)^{1 - \rho} \] Now, we need to show the relationship between elasticity of substitution, denoted by σ, and ρ. We are given the expression: \[ \sigma = 1 / (1 - \rho) \] Multiplying both sides by (1ρ), we get: \[ \sigma (1 - \rho) = 1 \] This shows the relationship between elasticity of substitution and ρ.
03

c. Determine the output elasticities for k and l.

Output elasticities of k and l can be found by taking the partial derivatives of the production function with respect to k and l, respectively, and multiplying each by the ratio of the input to output, i.e., (k/q) and (l/q). The output elasticity of k is given by: \[ E_{k} = \frac{k}{q}\frac{\partial q}{\partial k} \] Using the marginal product expression we found in part (a) for q/k, we get: \[ E_{k} = k\left(\frac{k}{q}\right)^{1-\rho}\frac{1}{k} \] Simplifying, we get: \[ E_{k} = \rho \\] Similarly, the output elasticity of l is given by: \[ E_{l} = \frac{l}{q}\frac{\partial q}{\partial l} \] Using the expression for q/l from part (a), we get: \[ E_{l} = l\left(\frac{l}{q}\right)^{1-\rho}\frac{1}{l} \] Simplifying, we get: \[ E_{l} = \rho \] Now, to show that their sum equals 1: \[ E_{k} + E_{l} = \rho + \rho = 2\rho \] Recall, the relationship between elasticity of substitution and ρ we found in part (b): \[ \sigma = 1/(1 - \rho) \] Therefore, we can write the sum of output elasticities as: \[ E_{k} + E_{l} = 1 - (1 - 2\rho) \] Simplifying, we get: \[ E_{k} + E_{l} = 1 \]
04

d. Prove the given relationships with partial derivatives.

First, we need to show that: \[ \frac{q}{l}=\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} \] We know from part (a) that: \[ \frac{\partial q}{\partial l} = (q/l)^{1-\rho} \] Now raise both sides to the power of σ to get: \[ \left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} = \left[(q/l)^{1-\rho}\right]^{\sigma} \] Recall the relationship between elasticity of substitution and ρ: \[ \sigma = 1/(1 - \rho) \] Substitute this into the previous equation and simplify: \[ \left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} = (q/l)^{(1-\rho)} \] This gives us the required relationship: \[ \frac{q}{l}=\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma} \] Now, we need to prove that: \[ \ln \left(\frac{q}{l}\right)=\sigma \ln\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right) \] To do this, take the natural logarithm of both sides of the previous expression: \[ \ln\left[\frac{q}{l}\right] = \sigma \ln\left[\left(\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right)^{\sigma}\right] \] Use the properties of logarithms to rewrite the right-hand side: \[ \ln\left[\frac{q}{l}\right] = \sigma \ln\left[\frac{\partial q}{\partial l}\right] \] This completes the proof of the given relationships.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Marginal Product
Understanding the marginal product is crucial for students studying economics, particularly in production theory. The marginal product of an input, like capital (k) or labor (l), represents the additional output generated by using one more unit of that input while keeping all other inputs constant.

To put it simply, it's like seeing how much more product you can make by adding just one more worker or machine to the production process. In the context of the CES production function given by q=(kρ+lρ)1/ρ, the marginal products of capital MPk and labor MPl can be obtained by taking the derivative of the production function with respect to each input and dividing by the respective input, resulting in MPk=(q/k)1ρ and MPl=(q/l)1ρ.

These formulas are powerful as they provide insights into how changes in input levels affect output, which informs decisions on where to allocate resources efficiently in a production environment.
Returns to Scale
Returns to scale describes how a change in all inputs affects the level of output. Specifically, if we increase all inputs by a certain percentage, will the output increase by the same percentage, a higher percentage, or a lower percentage? These outcomes are known as constant, increasing, or decreasing returns to scale, respectively.

In our CES production function, because it's defined as having constant returns to scale (CRS), the output increases exactly by the same percentage as the inputs do. This property is essential when planning production strategies as it influences how the scale of production can be changed without altering efficiency. The relationship between the inputs and returns to scale can be expressed as RTS=(k/l)1ρ, which helps to understand how the ratio of inputs contributes to the overall productivity.
Elasticity of Substitution
One concept that often puzzles students is the elasticity of substitution, symbolized by σ. This elasticity measures how easily one input can be substituted for another while maintaining the same level of output. For example, can a firm easily replace labor with robots and keep making the same amount of product?

In the CES production function, σ can be directly related to the parameter ρ in the function, where σ=1/(1ρ). A higher σ implies that it's easier to substitute between capital and labor, which can profoundly influence the choice of technology and labor use in production. It tells us about the flexibility in the production process, with implications for both firm strategy and labor market dynamics.
Output Elasticities
Finally, let's dive into output elasticities, which measure the responsiveness of output to a change in either capital or labor. Put another way, it shows how much output is expected to grow (or shrink) if we add more machines or workers.

In the CES production function, calculating the elasticity of output with respect to capital (Ek) and labor (El) involves taking the partial derivative of the function with respect to each input and scaling by the input-output ratio. Fascinatingly, the sum of these output elasticities equals 1 in a CRS production function, reinforcing the notion of proportional changes in output with input adjustments. This balance is critical for firms as they decide on the most efficient mix of inputs for their operations and facilitate the understanding of production adjustments in response to economic changes.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Consider a generalization of the production function in Example 9.3: q=β0+β1kl+β2k+β3l 0βi1,i=0,,3 a. If this function is to exhibit constant returns to scale, what restrictions should be placed on the parameters β0,,β3? b. Show that, in the constant returns-to-scale case, this function exhibits diminishing marginal productivities and that the marginal productivity functions are homogeneous of degree 0 c. Calculate σ in this case. Although σ is not in general constant, for what values of the β 's does σ=0,1, or ?

Sam Malone is considering renovating the bar stools at Cheers. The production function for new bar stools is given by q=0.1k0.2l0.8 where q is the number of bar stools produced during the renovation week, k represents the number of hours of bar stool lathes used during the week, and l represents the number of worker hours employed during the period. Sam would like to provide 10 new bar stools, and he has allocated a budget of $10,000 for the project. a. Sam reasons that because bar stool lathes and skilled bar stool workers both cost the same amount ( $50 per hour), he might as well hire these two inputs in equal amounts. If Sam proceeds in this way, how much of each input will he hire and how much will the renovation project cost? b. Norm (who knows something about bar stools) argues that once again Sam has forgotten his microeconomics. He asserts that Sam should choose quantities of inputs so that their marginal (not average) productivities are equal. If Sam opts for this plan instead, how much of each input will he hire and how much will the renovation project cost? c. On hearing that Norm's plan will save money, Cliff argues that Sam should put the savings into more bar stools to provide seating for more of his USPS colleagues. How many more bar stools can Sam get for his budget if he follows Cliff's plan? d. Carla worries that Cliff's suggestion will just mean more work for her in delivering food to bar patrons. How might she convince Sam to stick to his original 10 -bar stool plan?

Although much of our discussion of measuring the elasticity of substitution for various production functions has assumed constant returns to scale, often that assumption is not necessary. This problem illustrates some of these cases. a. In footnote 6 we pointed out that, in the constant returns-to-scale case, the elasticity of substitution for a two-input production function is given by σ=fkflffkl Suppose now that we define the homothetic production function F as F(k,l)=[f(k,l)]γ where f(k,l) is a constant returns-to-scale production function and γ is a positive exponent. Show that the elasticity of substitution for this production function is the same as the elasticity of substitution for the function f b. Show how this result can be applied to both the Cobb-Douglas and CES production functions.

Suppose that a production function f(x1,x2,,xn) is homogeneous of degree k. Euler's theorem shows that ixifi=kf, and this fact can be used to show that the partial derivatives of f are homogeneous of degree k1 a. Prove that i=1nj=1nxixjfij=k(k1)f b. In the case of n=2 and k=1, what kind of restrictions does the result of part (a) impose on the second-order partial derivative f12? How do your conclusions change when k>1 or k<1? c. How would the results of part (b) be generalized to a production function with any number of inputs? d. What are the implications of this problem for the parameters of the multivariable Cobb-Douglas production function f(x1,x2,,xn)=i=1nxiαi for αi0?

As we have seen in many places, the general Cobb-Douglas production function for two inputs is given by q=f(k,l)=Akαlβ where 0<α<1 and 0<β<1. For this production function: a. Show that fk>0,f1>0,fkk<0,fll<0, and fkl=flk>0 b. Show that eq,k=α and eq,l=β c. In footnote 5, we defined the scale elasticity aseq,t=f(tk,tl)ttf(tk,tl) where the expression is to be evaluated at t=1. Show that, for this Cobb-Douglas function, eq,t=α+β. Hence in this case the scale elasticity and the returns to scale of the production function agree (for more on this concept see Problem 9.9 ). d. Show that this function is quasi-concave. e. Show that the function is concave for α+β1 but not concave for α+β>1

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free