Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Graphing complements is complicated because a complementary relationship between goods (under Hicks' definition) cannot occur with only two goods. Rather, complementarity necessarily involves the demand relationships among three (or more) goods. In his review of complementarity, Samuelson provides a way of illustrating the concept with a two-dimensional indifference curve diagram (see the Suggested Readings). To examine this construction, assume there are three goods that a consumer might choose. The quantities of these are denoted by \(x_{1}, x_{2},\) and \(x_{3} .\) Now proceed as follows. a. Draw an indifference curve for \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3},\) holding the quantity of \(x_{1}\) constant at \(x_{1}^{0} .\) This indifference curve will have the customary convex shape. b. Now draw a second (higher) indifference curve for \(x_{2}, x_{3},\) holding \(x_{1}\) constant at \(x_{1}^{0}-h .\) For this new indifference curve, show the amount of extra \(x_{2}\) that would compensate this person for the loss of \(x_{1} ;\) call this amount \(j .\) Similarly, show that amount of extra \(x_{3}\) that would compensate for the loss of \(x_{1}\) and call this amount \(k\) c. Suppose now that an individual is given both amounts \(j\) and \(k\), thereby permitting him or her to move to an even higher \(x_{2}, x_{3}\) indifference curve. Show this move on your graph, and draw this new indifference curve. d. Samuelson now suggests the following definitions: If the new indifference curve corresponds to the indifference curve when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are independent. If the new indifference curve provides more utility than when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are complements. If the new indifference curve provides less utility than when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are substitutes. Show that these graphical definitions are symmetric. e. Discuss how these graphical definitions correspond to Hicks' more mathematical definitions given in the text. f. Looking at your final graph, do you think that this approach fully explains the types of relationships that might exist between \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3} ?\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Question: Analyze the relationships among three goods (\(x_1, x_2, x_3\)) using a two-dimensional indifference curve diagram, and determine if the graphical definitions of independent, complementary, and substitutive goods correspond to Hicks' mathematical definitions. Discuss the sufficiency of this approach for explaining relationships between \(x_2\) and \(x_3\). Answer: The graphical definitions of independent, complementary, and substitutive goods derived from the indifference curve analysis show that if the new indifference curve corresponds to the indifference curve when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), then goods 2 and 3 are independent; if the new indifference curve provides more utility than when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), they are complements; and if the new indifference curve provides less utility than when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), they are substitutes. These graphical definitions are symmetric and correspond to the mathematical definitions provided by Hicks. However, the approach may have limitations in fully explaining the possible relationships that might exist between \(x_2\) and \(x_3\). Additional investigation, such as examining consumer behavior, preferences, and constraints, may provide a more complete understanding.

Step by step solution

01

(a) Drawing indifference curve for \(x_2\) and \(x_3\) holding \(x_1\) constant

Draw an indifference curve for \(x_2\) and \(x_3\) in a two-dimensional plane, holding the quantity of \(x_1\) constant at \(x_1^0\). This curve will have a convex shape typical of indifference curves.
02

(b) Drawing a higher indifference curve while holding \(x_1\) constant at \(x_1^0 - h\)

Draw another (higher) indifference curve for \(x_2\) and \(x_3\), this time holding \(x_1\) constant at \(x_1^0 - h\). Show the amount of extra \(x_2\) that would compensate the person for the loss of \(x_1\) (call this amount \(j\)) and the amount of extra \(x_{3}\) that would compensate for the loss of \(x_1\) (call this amount \(k\)).
03

(c) Showing the move to a higher \(x_2, x_3\) indifference curve after receiving amounts \(j\) and \(k\)

Now assume that the individual is given both amounts \(j\) and \(k\). This allows them to move to an even higher \(x_2, x_3\) indifference curve. Show this move on the graph and draw the new indifference curve.
04

(d) Defining goods as independent, complements, or substitutes according to Samuelson's definitions

Using the new indifference curve and following Samuelson's definitions: - If the new indifference curve corresponds to the indifference curve when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), then goods 2 and 3 are independent. - If the new indifference curve provides more utility than when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), then goods 2 and 3 are complements. - If the new indifference curve provides less utility than when \(x_1 = x_1^0 - 2h\), then goods 2 and 3 are substitutes. Show that these graphical definitions are symmetric.
05

(e) Discussing correspondence between graphical definitions and Hicks' mathematical definitions

Discuss how the graphical definitions of independent, complementary, and substitutive goods derived from the indifference curve analysis correspond to the more mathematical definitions provided by Hicks in the text.
06

(f) Evaluating the sufficiency of this approach for explaining relationships between \(x_2\) and \(x_3\)

Looking at the final graph, consider whether this approach fully and accurately explains the possible relationships that might exist between \(x_2\) and \(x_3\). Discuss any limitations or potential improvements.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Complementary Goods
Complementary goods are products or services that tend to be used together, meaning the consumption of one enhances the consumption of the other. For instance, smartphones and data plans, or coffee and sugar, are typical examples of complementary goods. In microeconomic theory, when the price of one complementary good rises, the demand for the other tends to decrease, since consumers would derive less satisfaction from the use alone.

Indifference curve analysis helps to visualize this relationship. If an individual has less of one good, they would require more of its complement to maintain the same level of utility. This is depicted on an indifference curve by pinpointing the additional amount of one good needed to compensate for a reduction in another, preserving utility. If the new indifference curve after the adjustment lies above the original, this reflects the complementary nature of the goods in contributing to utility.
Substitute Goods
Substitute goods, in contrast, are goods that can replace each other in consumption, serving a similar purpose for the consumer. Examples include butter and margarine, or tea and coffee. In the context of indifference curves, substitute goods can be identified when a reduction in the quantity of one good can be offset by an equivalent increase in the other, with no loss in overall utility.

Illustrated graphically, if providing a consumer with more of one good does not compensate for a loss of another good, leading to a lower utility level on the new indifference curve, it indicates that the goods are substitutes. As such, the consumer doesn't derive a combined utility from their simultaneous consumption, which differentiates substitutes from complements in indifference curve analysis.
Microeconomic Theory
Microeconomic theory is the branch of economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources. It encompasses various concepts, including demand and supply, elasticity, consumer behavior, and market structures. Indifference curve analysis is a fundamental concept within microeconomic theory that demonstrates consumer preferences.

Through indifference curves, we can analyze how consumers would substitute between goods as prices change. This model assumes rationality, meaning consumers aim to maximize utility. Therefore, understanding how individuals react to changes in availability or the prices of goods (be it complementary or substitutive) is key for businesses, policymakers, and economists to predict market outcomes and consumer behavior. The graphical approach, combined with Hicks' mathematical definitions, forms a comprehensive basis for analyzing consumer choice, though real-world complexities sometimes necessitate more nuanced models.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Example 6.3 computes the demand functions implied by the three-good CES utility function \\[U(x, y, z)=-\frac{1}{x}-\frac{1}{y}-\frac{1}{z}.\\] a. Use the demand function for \(x\) in Equation 6.32 to determine whether \(x\) and \(y\) or \(x\) and \(z\) are gross substitutes or gross complements. b. How would you determine whether \(x\) and \(y\) or \(x\) and \(z\) are net substitutes or net complements?

Details of the analysis suggested in Problems 6.5 and 6.6 were originally worked out by Borcherding and Silberberg (see the Suggested Readings) based on a supposition first proposed by Alchian and Allen. These authors look at how a transaction charge affects the relative demand for two closely substitutable items. Assume that goods \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3}\) are close substitutes and are subject to a transaction charge of \(t\) per unit. Suppose also that good 2 is the more expensive of the two goods (i.e., "good apples" as opposed to "cooking apples". Hence the transaction charge lowers the relative price of the more expensive good [i.e., \(\left.\left(p_{2}+t\right) /\left(p_{3}+t\right) \text { decreases as } t \text { increases }\right] .\) This will increase the relative demand for the expensive good if \(\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right) / \partial t > 0\) (where we use compensated demand functions to eliminate pesky income effects). Borcherding and Silberberg show this result will probably hold using the following steps. a. Use the derivative of a quotient rule to expand \(\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right) / \partial t\). b. Use your result from part (a) together with the fact that, in this problem, \(\partial x_{i}^{\epsilon} / \partial t=\partial x_{i}^{c} / \partial p_{2}+\partial x_{i}^{\epsilon} / \partial p_{3}\) for \(i=2,3,\) to show that the derivative we seek can be written as \\[\frac{\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right)}{\partial t}=\frac{x_{2}^{c}}{x_{3}^{c}}\left[\frac{s_{22}}{x_{2}}+\frac{s_{23}}{x_{2}}-\frac{s_{32}}{x_{3}}-\frac{s_{33}}{x_{3}}\right],\\] \(\text { where } s_{i j}=\partial x_{i}^{c} / \partial p_{j}.\) c. Rewrite the result from part (b) in terms of compensated price elasticities: \\[e_{i j}^{c}=\frac{\partial x_{i}^{c}}{\partial p_{j}} \cdot \frac{p_{j}}{x_{i}^{c}},\\] d. Use Hicks' third law (Equation 6.26 ) to show that the term in brackets in parts (b) and (c) can now be written as \\[\left[\left(e_{22}-e_{23}\right)\left(1 / p_{2}-1 / p_{3}\right)+\left(e_{21}-e_{31}\right) / p_{3}\right].\\] e. Develop an intuitive argument about why the expression in part (d) is likely to be positive under the conditions of this problem. Hints: Why is the first product in the brackets positive? Why is the second term in brackets likely to be small? f. Return to Problem 6.6 and provide more complete explanations for these various findings.

A utility function is called separable if it can be written as \\[U(x, y)=U_{1}(x)+U_{2}(y),\\] where \(U_{i}^{\prime} > 0, U_{i}^{\prime \prime} < 0,\) and \(U_{1}, U_{2}\) need not be the same function. a. What does separability assume about the cross-partial derivative \(U_{x y}\) ? Give an intuitive discussion of what word this condition means and in what situations it might be plausible. b. Show that if utility is separable then neither good can be inferior. c. Does the assumption of separability allow you to conclude definitively whether \(x\) and \(y\) are gross substitutes or gross complements? Explain. d. Use the Cobb-Douglas utility function to show that separability is not invariant with respect to monotonic transformations. Note: Separable functions are examined in more detail in the Extensions to this chapter.

In Chapter \(5,\) we showed how the welfare costs of changes in a single price can be measured using expenditure functions and compensated demand curves. This problem asks you to generalize this to price changes in two (or many) goods. a. Suppose that an individual consumes \(n\) goods and that the prices of two of those goods (say, \(p_{1}\) and \(p_{2}\) ) increase. How would you use the expenditure function to measure the compensating variation (CV) for this person of such a price increase? b. A way to show these welfare costs graphically would be to use the compensated demand curves for goods \(x_{1}\) and \(x_{2}\) by assuming that one price increased before the other. Illustrate this approach. c. In your answer to part (b), would it matter in which order you considered the price changes? Explain. d. In general, would you think that the CV for a price increase of these two goods would be greater if the goods were net substitutes or net complements? Or would the relationship between the goods have no bearing on the welfare costs?

Hard Times Burt buys only rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts to sustain him. For Burt, rotgut whiskey is an inferior good that exhibits Giffen's paradox, although rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts are Hicksian substitutes in the customary sense. Develop an intuitive explanation to suggest why an increase in the price of rotgut whiskey must cause fewer jelly donuts to be bought. That is, the goods must also be gross complements.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free