Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

As defined in Chapter 3 , a utility function is homothetic if any straight line through the origin cuts all indifference curves at points of equal slope: The \(M R S\) depends on the ratio \(y / x\) a. Prove that, in this case, \(\partial x / \partial I\) is constant. b. Prove that if an individual's tastes can be represented by a homothetic indifference map then price and quantity must move in opposite directions; that is, prove that Giffen's paradox cannot occur.

Short Answer

Expert verified
Question: Show that in a homothetic utility function, (a) the partial derivative of x with respect to income is constant, and (b) Giffen's paradox cannot occur. Answer: (a) In a homothetic utility function, the partial derivative of x with respect to income is constant because the MRS only depends on the ratio y/x, and (b) Giffen's paradox cannot occur in a homothetic utility function as the demand for good x must decrease as its price increases, meaning that price and quantity must move in opposite directions.

Step by step solution

01

Part A: Proving that \(\partial x / \partial I\) is constant

Given a homothetic utility function where any straight line through the origin cuts all indifference curves at points of equal slope, we know that the \(MRS\) only depends on the ratio \(y/x\). We can denote the \(MRS\) function as follows: \(MRS(x,y) = f(\frac{y}{x})\) Now, consider the budget constraint of the individual with income \(I\) and prices \(p_x\) and \(p_y\): \(I = p_x x + p_y y\) To derive the demand for good \(x\), differentiate the budget constraint with respect to income \(I\): \(\frac{1}{p_x} = \frac{\partial x}{\partial I} + \frac{p_y}{p_x} \frac{\partial y}{\partial I}\) Now, using the homothetic property of the utility function, we can say: \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial y} = \frac{MRS(x,y)}{p_x/p_y}\) And replace the demand for good \(y\) in the above equation: \(\frac{1}{p_x} = \frac{\partial x}{\partial I} + \frac{p_y}{p_x} \frac{\partial x}{\partial I} \frac{MRS(x,y)}{p_x/p_y}\) Simplifying the equation: \(\frac{1}{p_x} = \frac{\partial x}{\partial I}(1 + MRS(x,y))\) Now, since \(MRS(x,y)\) depends only on the ratio \(y/x\), we can see that \(\partial x / \partial I\) is constant, proving part a of the exercise.
02

Part B: Proving that Giffen's paradox cannot occur

We now need to prove that if an individual's tastes are represented by a homothetic indifference map, Giffen's paradox cannot occur. For the paradox to happen, the demand for good \(x\) must increase as its price \(p_x\) increases, or \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial p_x} > 0\). Let's differentiate the demand for good \(x\) with respect to its price \(p_x\): \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial p_x} = \frac{-I}{p_x^2} + \frac{\partial x}{\partial I} \frac{-p_y y}{p_x^2} + \frac{\partial x}{\partial y} \frac{-p_y \partial y/\partial p_x}{p_x^2}\) Since we already know that \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial I}\) is constant and MRS only depends on the ratio \(y/x\), this equation can be simplified as: \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial p_x} = \frac{-I}{p_x^2} + C_1 \frac{-p_y y}{p_x^2} + C_2 \frac{-p_y \partial y/\partial p_x}{p_x^2}\) Where \(C_1\) and \(C_2\) are constants. Now, since all the terms on the right side of the equation are negative, it implies that the demand for good \(x\) must decrease as its price \(p_x\) increases: \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial p_x} < 0\) This proves that Giffen's paradox cannot occur if an individual's tastes are represented by a homothetic indifference map. Price and quantity must move in opposite directions.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Marginal Rate of Substitution
Understanding the Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is crucial for making sense of consumer behavior in economics. MRS highlights how willing a consumer is to substitute one good for another while maintaining the same level of utility. It's calculated as the absolute value of the slope of an indifference curve, representing various combinations of goods that provide equal satisfaction to the consumer.

In a homothetic utility function scenario, for any pair of goods, the MRS is the same along a ray from the origin, which means that consumer preferences exhibit consistent proportional trade-offs regardless of their consumption levels. This property ensures constancy in the rate at which a consumer is willing to trade between goods straight from the very first unit, and it's a critical aspect in proving both the constancy of \( \partial x / \partial I \) and the impossibility of Giffen's paradox in such context.
Giffen's Paradox
Giffen's paradox is a counterintuitive economic phenomenon where a rise in the price of a 'Giffen good' leads to an increase in its quantity demanded, contrary to the law of demand. This paradox mainly occurs with inferior goods—products that consumers buy more of as their income decreases. The paradox hinges on the income effect of a price increase outweighing the substitution effect.

In the realm of homothetic utility functions, this paradox does not materialize because the substitution and income effects move in harmony due to consistent MRS. When the price of a good goes up, consumers consistently switch to other goods, ensuring the quantity demanded for the pricier good decreases, keeping the relationship between price and quantity demanded in its conventional downward slope.
Indifference Curves
Indifference curves represent a fundamental concept in understanding consumer choices. These curves graphically portray various bundles of goods that provide the same level of utility or satisfaction to a consumer. The shape and slope of these curves can reveal a lot about consumer preferences.

In a homothetic context, indifference curves are straight lines through the origin, signifying that consumer preferences remain proportional as the consumption of goods changes. The equal slope at all points along the rays from the origin means that the MRS is consistent across different levels of consumption, simplifying the analysis of consumer behavior and demand.
Budget Constraint
The budget constraint is a line that represents the combination of goods a consumer can purchase with their limited income, given the prices of the goods. This constraint reflects the trade-offs a consumer has to consider given their budgetary limitations.

With the exercise involving homothetic utility functions, we see how the budget constraint interacts closely with the constancy of MRS and ultimately simplifies the process of deriving demand for a good. The slope of the budget constraint helps inform the consumer's optimal choice by pinpointing where they can get the most satisfaction for their available income, which in homothetic preferences results in a consistent response to income and price changes for any given good.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

As in Example 5.1 , assume that utility is given by \\[ \text { utility }=U(x, y)=x^{0.3} y^{0.7} \\] a. Use the uncompensated demand functions given in Example 5.1 to compute the indirect utility function and the expenditure function for this case. b. Use the expenditure function calculated in part (a) together with Shephard's lemma to compute the compensated demand function for good \(x\) c. Use the results from part (b) together with the uncompensated demand function for good \(x\) to show that the Slutsky equation holds for this case.

David N. gets \(\$ 3\) per week as an allowance to spend any way he pleases. Because he likes only peanut butter and jelly sandwiches, he spends the entire amount on peanut butter (at \(\$ 0.05\) per ounce) and jelly (at \(\$ 0.10\) per ounce). Bread is provided free of charge by a concerned neighbor. David is a particular eater and makes his sandwiches with exactly 1 ounce of jelly and 2 ounces of peanut butter. He is set in his ways and will never change these proportions. a. How much peanut butter and jelly will David buy with his \(\$ 3\) allowance in a week? b. Suppose the price of jelly were to increase to \(\$ 0.15\) an ounce. How much of each commodity would be bought? c. By how much should David's allowance be increased to compensate for the increase in the price of jelly in part (b)? d. Graph your results in parts (a) to (c). e. In what sense does this problem involve only a single commodity, peanut butter and jelly sandwiches? Graph the demand curve for this single commodity. f. Discuss the results of this problem in terms of the income and substitution effects involved in the demand for jelly.

Consider a simple quasi-linear utility function of the form \(U(x, y)=x+\ln y\) a. Calculate the income effect for each good. Also calculate the income elasticity of demand for each good. b. Calculate the substitution effect for each good. Also calculate the compensated own-price elasticity of demand for each good. c. Show that the Slutsky equation applies to this function. d. Show that the elasticity form of the Slutsky equation also applies to this function. Describe any special features you observe.

The general form for the expenditure function of the almost ideal demand system (AIDS) is given by $$\ln E\left(p_{1}, \ldots, p_{n}, U\right)=a_{0}+\sum_{i=1}^{n} \alpha_{i} \ln p_{i}+\frac{1}{2} \sum_{i=1}^{n} \sum_{j=1}^{n} \gamma_{i j} \ln p_{i} \ln p_{j}+U \beta_{0} \prod_{i=1}^{k} p_{k}^{\beta_{k}}$$ For analytical ease, assume that the following restrictions apply:For analytical ease, assume that the following restrictions apply: $$\gamma_{i j}=\gamma_{j i}, \quad \sum_{i=1}^{n} \alpha_{i}=1, \quad \text { and } \quad \sum_{j=1}^{n} \gamma_{i j}=\sum_{k=1}^{n} \beta_{k}=0$$ a. Derive the AIDS functional form for a two-goods case. b. Given the previous restrictions, show that this expenditure function is homogeneous of degree 1 in all prices. This, along with the fact that this function resembles closely the actual data, makes it an "ideal" function. c. Using the fact that \(s_{x}=\frac{d \ln E}{d \ln p_{x}}\) (see Problem 5.8 ), calculate the income share of each of the two goods.

The three aggregation relationships presented in this chapter can be generalized to any number of goods. This problem asks the following elasticities: $$\begin{array}{l} e_{i, I}=\frac{\partial x_{i}}{\partial I} \cdot \frac{I}{x_{i}} \\ e_{i, j}=\frac{\partial x_{i}}{\partial p_{j}} \cdot \frac{p_{j}}{x_{i}} \end{array}$$ Use this notation to show: a. Homogeneity: \(\sum_{j=1}^{n}=e_{i, j}+e_{i, l}=0\) b. Engel aggregation: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n}=s_{i} e_{i, l}=1\) c. Cournot aggregation: \(\sum_{i=1}^{n} s_{i} e_{i, j}=-s_{j}\)

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free