Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The analysis of public goods in this chapter exclusively used a model with only two individuals. The results are readily generalized to n persons-a generalization pursued in this problem. a. With n persons in an economy, what is the condition for efficient production of a public good? Explain how the characteristics of the public good are reflected in these conditions. b. What is the Nash equilibrium in the provision of this public good to n persons? Explain why this equilibrium is inefficient. Also explain why the underprovision of this public good is more severe than in the two-person cases studied in the chapter. c. How is the Lindahl solution generalized to n persons? Is the existence of a Lindahl equilibrium guaranteed in this more complex model?

Short Answer

Expert verified
The condition for efficient production of public goods in an economy with n persons is given by the following equation: i=1nMBi=MC, where MBi represents the marginal benefit for person i, and MC represents the marginal cost of producing the public good. This condition is required for efficient production because it ensures that the combined willingness to pay (marginal benefits) of all persons is equal to the marginal cost of producing the public good, taking into account the non-rivalry and non-excludability characteristics of the public good, which ensure that it is accessible to all persons without increasing costs or causing underprovision.

Step by step solution

01

a) Condition for Efficient Production of Public Good

To find the condition for efficient production of the public good for n persons, we need to consider the combined willingness to pay (marginal benefit) for each person's demand for the public good, as well as the marginal cost of producing the public good. This can be expressed as: i=1nMBi=MC Where: - MBi is the marginal benefit for person i - MC is the marginal cost of producing the public good This condition is required for the efficient production of the public good because it ensures that the combined willingness to pay (marginal benefits) of all persons is equal to the marginal cost of producing the public good. The characteristics of the public good, i.e., non-rivalry and non-excludability, are reflected in this condition as they ensure that the public good is accessible to all persons without increasing the cost of production or causing it to be underprovided.
02

b) Nash Equilibrium and Inefficiency

The Nash equilibrium for the provision of the public good to n persons occurs when each person chooses the optimal level of the public good, given the choices of others. This equilibrium is inefficient because it results in an underprovision of the public good. The main reason for this underprovision is the free-rider problem, where individuals have an incentive not to contribute (or under-contribute) to the public good, hoping that others will cover the cost. The inefficiency of the Nash equilibrium is more severe in the case of n-person compared to the two-person case. As the number of individuals in the economy increases, the weight of the individual's contribution decreases, which leads to an increased incentive for an individual to free-ride and rely on others to provide the public good. This causes the overall provision of the public good to be lower than the efficient level.
03

c) Generalization of Lindahl Solution and Existence

The Lindahl solution is a concept that assigns a personalized price to each of the n persons based on their willingness to pay for the public good. The personalized price reflects the proportion that each individual contributes towards the total cost of providing the public good. The generalized Lindahl solution for an economy with n persons can be expressed as follows: i=1nMBiPi=MC Where: - Pi is the personalized price for person i The existence of a Lindahl equilibrium is not guaranteed in this more complex model. Although the Lindahl solution aims to address the free-rider problem and achieve efficiency, it relies heavily on perfect information about individual preferences and accurate allocation of personalized prices. These requirements can be challenging to fulfill in practice, especially in large economies with a diverse population, leading to the nonexistence of the Lindahl equilibrium.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

On the island of Pago Pago there are 2 lakes and 20 anglers. Each angler can fish on either lake and keep the average catch on his particular lake. On Lake x, the total number of fish caught is given by \[ F^{x}=10 l_{x}-\frac{1}{2} l_{x}^{2} \] where lx is the number of people fishing on the lake. For Lake y, the relationship is \[ F^{y}=5 l_{y} \] a. Under this organization of society, what will be the total number of fish caught? b. The chief of Pago Pago, having once read an economics book, believes it is possible to increase the total number of fish caught by restricting the number of people allowed to fish on Lake x. What number should be allowed to fish on Lake x in order to maximize the total catch of fish? What is the number of fish caught in this situation? c. Being opposed to coercion, the chief decides to require a fishing license for Lake x. If the licensing procedure is to bring about the optimal allocation of labor, what should the cost of a license be (in terms of fish)? d. Explain how this example sheds light on the connection between property rights and externalities.

Suppose there are only two individuals in society. Person A 's demand curve for mosquito control is given by \[ q_{n}=100-p \] for person B, the demand curve for mosquito control is given by \[ q_{b}=200-p \] a. Suppose mosquito control is a pure public good; that is, once it is produced, everyone benefits from it. What would be the optimal level of this activity if it could be produced at a constant marginal cost of $120 per unit? b. If mosquito control were left to the private market, how much might be produced? Does your answer depend on what each person assumes the other will do? c. If the government were to produce the optimal amount of mosquito control, how much will this cost? How should the tax bill for this amount be allocated between the individuals if they are to share it in proportion to benefits received from mosquito control?

Suppose individuals face a probability of u that they will be unemployed next year. If they are unemployed they will receive unemployment benefits of b, whereas if they are employed they receive w(1t), where t is the tax used to finance unemployment benefits. Unemployment benefits are constrained by the government budget constraint ub=tw(1u) a. Suppose the individual's utility function is given by \[ U=\left(y_{i}\right)^{\delta} / \delta \] where 1δ is the degree of constant relative risk aversion. What would be the utility-maximizing choices for b and t? b. How would the utility-maximizing choices for b and t respond to changes in the probability of unemployment, u ? c. How would b and t change in response to changes in the risk aversion parameter δ ?

There is considerable legal controversy about product safety. Two extreme positions might be termed caveat emptor (let the buyer beware) and caveat vendor (let the seller beware). Under the former scheme producers would have no responsibility for the safety of their products: Buyers would absorb all losses. Under the latter scheme this liability assignment would be reversed: Firms would be completely responsible under law for losses incurred from unsafe products. Using simple supply and demand analysis, discuss how the assignment of such liability might affect the allocation of resources. Would safer products be produced if firms were strictly liable under law? How do possible information asymmetries affect your results?

Suppose the oil industry in Utopia is perfectly competitive and that all firms draw oil from a single (and practically inexhaustible) pool. Assume that each competitor believes that it can sell all the oil it can produce at a stable world price of $10 per barrel and that the cost of operating a well for one year is $1,000 Total output per year (Q) of the oil field is a function of the number of wells ( n ) operating in the field. In particular, \[ Q=500 n-n^{2} \] and the amount of oil produced by each well ( q ) is given by \[ q=\frac{Q}{n}=500-n \] a. Describe the equilibrium output and the equilibrium number of wells in this perfectly competitive case. Is there a divergence between private and social marginal cost in the industry? b. Suppose now that the government nationalizes the oil field. How many oil wells should it operate? What will total output be? What will the output per well be? c. As an alternative to nationalization, the Utopian government is considering an annual license fee per well to discourage overdrilling. How large should this license fee be if it is to prompt the industry to drill the optimal number of wells?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free