Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose individuals face a probability of \(u\) that they will be unemployed next year. If they are unemployed they will receive unemployment benefits of \(b,\) whereas if they are employed they receive \(w(1-t),\) where \(t\) is the tax used to finance unemployment benefits. Unemployment benefits are constrained by the government budget constraint \(u b=t w(1-u)\) a. Suppose the individual's utility function is given by \\[ U=\left(y_{i}\right)^{\delta} / \delta \\] where \(1-\delta\) is the degree of constant relative risk aversion. What would be the utility-maximizing choices for \(b\) and \(t ?\) b. How would the utility-maximizing choices for \(b\) and \(t\) respond to changes in the probability of unemployment, \(u\) ? c. How would \(b\) and \(t\) change in response to changes in the risk aversion parameter \(\delta\) ?

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: As the probability of unemployment (u) increases, the optimal tax rate (t) decreases, while the optimal unemployment benefits (b) increases. As the risk aversion parameter (δ) increases, the optimal tax rate (t) decreases, and the optimal unemployment benefits (b) also decrease.

Step by step solution

01

Find the expected utility

Given the individual's utility function and the probability of being employed and unemployed, we can find the expected utility (Eu) as follows: \[ Eu = u\frac{(b)^\delta}{\delta} + (1-u)\frac{((1-t)w)^\delta}{\delta} \]
02

Set up the constraint

The government budget constraint is given as: \[u b = t w (1-u)\]
03

Substitute the budget constraint into the expected utility equation

Express b in terms of t from the budget constraint: \[ b = \frac{t w (1-u)}{u} \] Now substitute this back into the expected utility equation: \[ Eu = u\frac{(\frac{t w (1-u)}{u})^\delta}{\delta} + (1-u)\frac{((1-t)w)^\delta}{\delta} \]
04

Differentiate the expected utility

To find the utility-maximizing choices for b and t, we need to differentiate Eu with respect to t and set the resulting expression equal to 0: \[ \frac{\partial Eu}{\partial t} = u\frac{(\frac{w (1-u)}{u})^\delta \cdot w}{\delta} - (1-u)\frac{(w)^\delta}{\delta} = 0 \]
05

Solve for the optimal tax (t)

From the equation in Step 4, we can express t as: \[ t = \frac{u^{1-\delta}}{1-\delta} \]
06

Find the optimal unemployment benefits (b)

Substituting the optimal tax value back into the constraint equation, we get the optimal unemployment benefits (b): \[ b = \frac{\frac{u^{1-\delta}}{1-\delta} w (1-u)}{u} \]
07

Analyze the effect of changes in the probability of unemployment (u)

For part (b), we can see from our solution that as u increases, the optimal tax rate t would decrease, while the optimal unemployment benefits b would increase. This is because when the probability of unemployment is higher, it is preferred to have a larger payout from the unemployment benefits, while simultaneously reducing the tax burden on employed individuals.
08

Analyze the effect of changes in the risk aversion parameter (δ)

For part (c), as the risk aversion parameter δ increases, the optimal tax rate t would decrease since the denominator (1-δ) increases, while the optimal unemployment benefits b would also decrease. This means that more risk-averse individuals prefer more insurance against unemployment, so they are willing to have a lower tax rate and receive lower unemployment benefits. Conversely, less risk-averse individuals want less insurance and thus require higher tax rates and unemployment benefits.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose there are only two individuals in society. Person \(A\) 's demand curve for mosquito control is given by \\[ q_{n}=100-p \\] for person \(\mathrm{B}\), the demand curve for mosquito control is given by \\[ q_{b}=200-p \\] a. Suppose mosquito control is a pure public good; that is, once it is produced, everyone benefits from it. What would be the optimal level of this activity if it could be produced at a constant marginal cost of \(\$ 120\) per unit? b. If mosquito control were left to the private market, how much might be produced? Does your answer depend on what each person assumes the other will do? c. If the government were to produce the optimal amount of mosquito control, how much will this cost? How should the tax bill for this amount be allocated between the individuals if they are to share it in proportion to benefits received from mosquito control?

Suppose the oil industry in Utopia is perfectly competitive and that all firms draw oil from a single (and practically inexhaustible) pool. Assume that each competitor believes that it can sell all the oil it can produce at a stable world price of \(\$ 10\) per barrel and that the cost of operating a well for one year is \(\$ 1,000\) Total output per year (Q) of the oil field is a function of the number of wells ( \(n\) ) operating in the field. In particular, \\[ Q=500 n-n^{2} \\] and the amount of oil produced by each well ( \(q\) ) is given by \\[ q=\frac{Q}{n}=500-n \\] a. Describe the equilibrium output and the equilibrium number of wells in this perfectly competitive case. Is there a divergence between private and social marginal cost in the industry? b. Suppose now that the government nationalizes the oil field. How many oil wells should it operate? What will total output be? What will the output per well be? c. As an alternative to nationalization, the Utopian government is considering an annual license fee per well to discourage overdrilling. How large should this license fee be if it is to prompt the industry to drill the optimal number of wells?

There is considerable legal controversy about product safety. Two extreme positions might be termed caveat emptor (let the buyer beware) and caveat vendor (let the seller beware). Under the former scheme producers would have no responsibility for the safety of their products: Buyers would absorb all losses. Under the latter scheme this liability assignment would be reversed: Firms would be completely responsible under law for losses incurred from unsafe products. Using simple supply and demand analysis, discuss how the assignment of such liability might affect the allocation of resources. Would safer products be produced if firms were strictly liable under law? How do possible information asymmetries affect your results?

Suppose the production possibility frontier for an economy that produces one public good ( \(y\) ) and one private good \((x)\) is given by \\[ x^{2}+100 y^{2}=5,000 \\] This economy is populated by 100 identical individuals, each with a utility function of the form \\[ \text { utility }=\sqrt{x_{i} y} \\] where \(x_{i}\) is the individual's share of private good production \((=x / 100) .\) Notice that the public good is nonexclusive and that everyone benefits equally from its level of production. a. If the market for \(x\) and \(y\) were perfectly competitive, what levels of those goods would be produced? What would the typical individual's utility be in this situation? b. What are the optimal production levels for \(x\) and \(y\) ? What would the typical individual's utility level be? How should consumption of good \(x\) be taxed to achieve this result? Hint: The numbers in this problem do not come out evenly, and some approximations should suffice.

On the island of Pago Pago there are 2 lakes and 20 anglers. Each angler can fish on either lake and keep the average catch on his particular lake. On Lake \(x\), the total number of fish caught is given by \\[ F^{x}=10 l_{x}-\frac{1}{2} l_{x}^{2} \\] where \(l_{x}\) is the number of people fishing on the lake. For Lake \(y,\) the relationship is \\[ F^{y}=5 l_{y} \\] a. Under this organization of society, what will be the total number of fish caught? b. The chief of Pago Pago, having once read an economics book, believes it is possible to increase the total number of fish caught by restricting the number of people allowed to fish on Lake \(x .\) What number should be allowed to fish on Lake \(x\) in order to maximize the total catch of fish? What is the number of fish caught in this situation? c. Being opposed to coercion, the chief decides to require a fishing license for Lake \(x\). If the licensing procedure is to bring about the optimal allocation of labor, what should the cost of a license be (in terms of fish)? d. Explain how this example sheds light on the connection between property rights and externalities.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free