Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Following in the spirit of the labor market game described in Example \(16.6,\) suppose the firm's total revenue function is given by \\[ R=10 l-l^{2} \\] and the union's utility is simply a function of the total wage bill: \\[ U(w, l)=w l \\] a. What is the Nash equilibrium wage contract in the two-stage game described in Example \(16.6 ?\) b. Show that the alternative wage contract \(w^{\prime}=l^{\prime}=4\) is Pareto superior to the contract identified in part (a). c. Under what conditions would the contract described in part (b) be sustainable as a subgame-perfect equilibrium?

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary, we analyzed a two-stage game between a firm and a union. The Nash equilibrium wage contract was determined to be (w, l) = (\\(\frac{10}{3}\\), \\(\frac{10}{3}\\)). We then showed that an alternative wage contract (w', l') = (4, 4) is Pareto superior to the Nash equilibrium contract. Finally, we determined that the alternative wage contract can be sustained as a subgame-perfect equilibrium, as both parties have no incentives to deviate from the agreed contract.

Step by step solution

01

a. Finding the Nash equilibrium wage contract

To find the Nash equilibrium wage contract, we will first determine the best response functions for both the union and the firm. Given the total revenue function R and the union's utility function U, we set up the following optimization problems: 1. Union's maximization problem: \\[ Max_{l} U(w, l) = wl \\] 2. Firm's maximization problem: \\[ Max_{w} \pi(w, l) = R(l) - wl \\] First, we need to find the union's best response function by solving its maximization problem. The utility function is linear in l, so the best response function will be simply the highest wage possible given w:
02

Find the best response for the union

Since the utility function is linear, the union's best response function will be: \\[ l^{u}(w) = w \\] Now let's find the firm's best response function.
03

Find the best response for the firm

The firm's maximization problem is given by: \\[ \pi(w, l) = R(l) - wl = 10l - l^2 - wl \\] Taking the first-order derivative with respect to l and setting it equal to 0: \\[ \frac{\partial \pi}{\partial l} = 10 - 2l - w = 0 \Rightarrow l^{f}(w) = \frac{10 - w}{2} \\] Having obtained both best response functions, we can find the Nash equilibrium by setting them equal to each other.
04

Find the Nash equilibrium wage contract

To find the Nash equilibrium, equate the best response functions: \\[ l^{u}(w) = l^{f}(w) \\] \\[ w = \frac{10 - w}{2} \Rightarrow w = \frac{10}{3} \\] Plugging this value back into one of the best response functions, back into the Nash equilibrium l: \\[ l = \frac{10 - \frac{10}{3}}{2} = \frac{10}{3} \\] So, the Nash equilibrium wage contract in the two-stage game is (w, l) = (\\(\frac{10}{3}\\), \\(\frac{10}{3}\\)).
05

b. Showing the alternative wage contract is Pareto superior

Now to show that the alternative wage contract (w', l') = (4,4) is Pareto superior to the contract (w, l) = (\\(\frac{10}{3}\\), \\(\frac{10}{3}\\)), we need to verify if both the union and the firm are better off with the alternative contract. 1. Union's utility with the alternative contract: \\[ U(w', l') = w'l' = 4 \times 4 = 16 \\] 2. Union's utility with the Nash equilibrium contract: \\[ U(w, l) = wl = \frac{10}{3} \times \frac{10}{3} = \frac{100}{9} \\] Since \\( U(w', l') > U(w, l)\\), the union is better off with the alternative contract. 3. Firm's profit with the alternative contract: \\[ \pi(w', l') = R(l') - w'l' = 10 \times 4 - 4^2 - 4 \times 4 = 8 \\] 4. Firm's profit with the Nash equilibrium contract: \\[ \pi(w, l) = R(l) - wl = 10 \times \frac{10}{3} - \frac{10^2}{9} - \frac{100}{3} \Rightarrow \pi(w, l) = \frac{20}{9} \\] Since \\( \pi(w', l') > \pi(w, l)\\), the firm is also better off with the alternative contract. Thus, the alternative wage contract (w', l') = (4, 4) is Pareto superior to the contract (w, l) = (\\(\frac{10}{3}\\), \\(\frac{10}{3}\\)).
06

c. Conditions for alternative contract to be a subgame-perfect equilibrium

For the alternative contract (w', l') = (4, 4) to be sustainable as a subgame-perfect equilibrium, both the union and the firm must have no incentives to deviate from the agreed contract. In other words, each party's payoff from the alternative contract should be greater than or equal to their best response payoffs given the other party's choice. Mathematically, this means: 1. For the union, \\( U(w', l') \ge U(w, l^{u}(w'))\\) 2. For the firm, \\( \pi(w', l') \ge \pi(w^{f}(l'), l')\\) But since we established in part (b) that both parties are better off with the alternative contract, these conditions are satisfied, and thus the alternative wage contract (w', l') = (4, 4) can be sustained as a subgame-perfect equilibrium.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Labor Market Game
In the context of microeconomics, the term 'labor market game' refers to a strategic interaction between two key players in the labor market: a firm and a union. This game is structured to reflect the negotiation process for wages and employment levels. To simplify, imagine the labor market as a kind of tug-of-war, where the firm aims to maximize profits and the union strives to secure the best possible wage for its members.

The 'game' starts with each player possessing a set of strategies. In our textbook example, the firm can choose a level of labor, which indirectly affects the wage rate since the union’s utility depends on the total wage bill (the product of wages and employment level). The outcome of this strategic interaction is typically a wage contract that both parties agree upon.

However, what's intriguing about such a game are the concepts of Nash equilibrium and Pareto superiority. In Nash equilibrium, neither party can improve their situation without making the other party worse off, given the choice of the other player. Meanwhile, a Pareto superior outcome implies a situation where at least one party is better off, and no one is worse off—a concept that is closely related to the idea of efficiency in economics.
Total Revenue Function
The total revenue function is a mathematical representation of how a firm’s revenue changes with varying levels of output or, in the case of our labor market game, the level of labor hired. In simple terms, the total revenue function illustrates how the money coming into a firm increases or decreases as it hires more or fewer workers.

Within our provided textbook problem, the total revenue function is expressed as \( R = 10l - l^2 \), where \( R \) stands for total revenue and \( l \) represents the level of labor. This quadratic function suggests that initially, hiring more labor increases total revenue at a decreasing rate due to the negative squared term, reflecting the law of diminishing returns. However, beyond a certain point, hiring additional labor actually decreases total revenue.

This total revenue function serves as a critical foundation for the firm's decision-making process. By comparing the cost of labor against the revenue labor produces, the firm can determine the optimal level of labor \textemdash the exact point where the difference between the revenue generated and the cost of labor is at its maximum, or in other words, where the firm's profit is maximized.
Union's Utility Function
The union's utility function is key to understanding the union’s objectives and how it responds to different wage contracts. Think of 'utility' as a measure of satisfaction or preference—it encapsulates what the union values. For the union in our labor market game, utility is derived from the total wage bill, as represented by the function \( U(w, l) = wl \).

This linear utility function signifies that the union’s utility increases directly with the wage rate, \( w \), and the level of labor, \( l \). The higher the total wage bill, the happier the union members are because it represents the total amount of remuneration paid to them for their work.

When analyzing scenarios of wage contracts, the union will aim for the outcome that maximizes its utility. However, it must also consider the firm's response, as well as any equilibria that can arise from the strategic interplay between the union's desire for higher wages and the firm's pursuit of profit maximization. A deeper grasp of the union’s utility function assists us in predicting and explaining the nature of the wage contracts that are agreed upon, including how variations in these contracts could lead to more efficient or equitable outcomes for both parties.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

A welfare program for low-income people offers a family a basic grant of \(\$ 6,000\) per year. This grant is reduced by \(\$ 0.75\) for each \(\$ 1\) of other income the family has. a. How much in welfare benefits does the family receive if it has no other income? If the head of the family earns \(\$ 2,000\) per year? How about \(\$ 4,000\) per year? b. At what level of earnings does the welfare grant become zero? c. Assume the head of this family can earn \(\$ 4\) per hour and that the family has no other income. What is the annual budget constraint for this family if it does not participate in the welfare program? That is, how are consumption ( \(c\) ) and hours of leisure ( \(h\) ) related? What is the budget constraint if the family opts to participate in the welfare program? (Remember, the welfare grant can only be positive. e. Graph your results from parts (c) and (d). f. Suppose the government changes the rules of the welfare program to permit families to keep 50 percent of what they earn. How would this change your answers to parts (d) and (e)? g. Using your results from part (f), can you predict whether the head of this family will work more or less under the new rules described in part (f)?

Carl the clothier owns a large garment factory on an isolated island. Carl's factory is the only source of employment for most of the islanders, and thus Carl acts as a monopsonist. The supply curve for garment workers is given by \\[ l=80 w \\] where \(l\) is the number of workers hired and \(w\) is their hourly wage. Assume also that Carl's labor demand (marginal revenue product \()\) curve is given by \\[ l=400-40 M R P_{1} \\] a. How many workers will Carl hire to maximize his profits, and what wage will he pay? b. Assume now that the government implements a minimum wage law covering all garment workers. How many workers will Carl now hire, and how much unemployment will there be if the minimum wage is set at \(\$ 4\) per hour? c. Graph your results. under perfect competition? (Assume the minimum wage is above the market- determined wage.)

Suppose demand for labor is given by \\[ l=-50 w+450 \\] and supply is given by \\[ l=100 w \\] where \(l\) represents the number of people employed and \(w\) is the real wage rate per hour. a. What will be the equilibrium levels for \(w\) and \(l\) in this market? b. Suppose the government wishes to increase the equilibrium wage to \(\$ 4\) per hour by offering a subsidy to employers for each person hired. How much will this subsidy have to be? What will the new equilibrium level of employment be? How much total subsidy will be paid? c. Suppose instead that the government declared a minimum wage of \(\$ 4\) per hour. How much labor would be demanded at this price? How much unemployment would there be? d. Graph your results.

The Ajax Coal Company is the only hirer of labor in its area. It can hire any number of female workers or male workers it wishes. The supply curve for women is given by \\[ l_{f}=100 w_{f} \\] and for men by \\[ l_{m}=9 w_{m}^{2} \\] where \(w_{f}\) and \(w_{m}\) are the hourly wage rates paid to female and male workers, respectively. Assume that Ajax sells its coal in a perfectly competitive market at \(\$ 5\) per ton and that each worker hired (both men and women) can mine 2 tons per hour. If the firm wishes to maximize profits, how many female and male workers should be hired, and what will the wage rates be for these two groups? How much will Ajax earn in profits per hour on its mine machinery? How will that result compare to one in which Ajax was constrained (say, by market forces) to pay all workers the same wage based on the value of their marginal products?

The theory developed in this chapter treats labor supply as the mirror image of the demand for leisure. Hence, the entire body of demand theory developed in Part 2 of the text becomes relevant to the study of labor supply as well. Here are three examples. a. Roy's identity. In the Extensions to Chapter 5 we showed how demand functions can be derived from indirect utility functions by using Roy's identity. Use a similar approach to show that the labor supply function associated with the utility. maximization problem described in Equation 16.20 can be derived from the indirect utility function by \\[ l(w, n)=\frac{\partial V(w, n) / \partial w}{\partial V(w, n) / \partial n} \\] Illustrate this result for the Cobb-Douglas case described in Example 16.1 b. Substitutes and complements. A change in the real wage will affect not only labor supply, but also the demand for specific items in the preferred consumption bundle. Develop a Slutsky-type equation for the cross-price effect of a change in \(w\) on a particular consumption item and then use it to discuss whether leisure and the item are (net or gross) substitutes or complements. Provide an example of each type of relationship. c. Labor supply and marginal expense. Use a derivation similar to that used to calculate marginal revenue for a given demand curve to show that \(M E_{l}=w\left(1+1 / e_{l} w\right)\).

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free