Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Consider the following Bertrand game involving two firms producing differentiated products. Firms have no costs of production. Firm 1's demand is \\[ q_{1}=1-p_{1}+b p_{2} \\] where \(b > 0 .\) A symmetric equation holds for firm 2 's demand. a. Solve for the Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous price-choice game. b. Compute the firms' outputs and profits. c. Represent the equilibrium on a best-response function diagram. Show how an increase in \(b\) would change the equilibrium. Draw a representative isoprofit curve for firm 1

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: As the differentiation parameter \(b\) increases, the Nash equilibrium prices for both firms increase, while their outputs remain constant at a half. The profits for both firms also increase due to higher equilibrium prices. This increase in differentiation leads to steeper best-response functions, as each firm becomes less sensitive to the other firm's actions, allowing them to charge higher prices without losing too much market share.

Step by step solution

01

Find the profit functions of both firms.

To find the Nash equilibrium prices, we first need to find the profit functions for both firms. Since there are no costs, profit is simply given by revenue, which can be calculated as price times quantity. For firm 1, the profit function is: \\[ \pi_{1} = p_{1}q_{1} = p_{1}(1 - p_{1} + b p_{2}) \\] Similarly, for firm 2, the profit function is: \\[ \pi_{2} = p_{2}q_{2} = p_{2}(1 - p_{2} + b p_{1}) \\]
02

Find the Best-Response functions of both firms.

Now we need to find the best-response functions of both firms by maximizing their profits. To do this, we take the first derivative of the profit functions concerning their respective prices and set them equal to zero. For firm 1, the first-order condition is: \\[ \frac{\partial \pi_{1}}{\partial p_{1}} = 1 - 2 p_{1} + b p_{2} = 0 \\] For firm 2, the first-order condition is: \\[ \frac{\partial \pi_{2}}{\partial p_{2}} = 1 - 2 p_{2} + b p_{1} = 0 \\]
03

Solve the system of equations.

We now have a system of two linear equations with two unknowns (\(p_{1}\) and \(p_{2}\)). We can solve this system to find the Nash equilibrium prices. From the first-order condition for firm 1, we can solve for \(p_1\): \\[ p_{1} = \frac{1 + b p_{2}}{2} \\] Substitute this expression for \(p_1\) into the first-order condition for firm 2: \\[ 1 - 2 p_{2} + b \left(\frac{1 + b p_{2}}{2}\right) = 0 \\] Solve for \(p_2\): \\[ p_{2} = \frac{1}{2(2 - b)} \\] Substitute the expression for \(p_2\) back into the expression for \(p_1\): \\[ p_{1} = \frac{1 + b\left(\frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\right)}{2} = \frac{1}{2(2 - b)} \\] Thus, the Nash equilibrium prices are \(p_{1}^* = p_{2}^* = \frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\). #b. Computing outputs and profits#
04

Calculate companies' quantities.

Now that we have the Nash equilibrium prices, we can calculate the output of both firms by plugging these prices into their respective demand functions. For firm 1: \\[ q_{1}^* = 1 - p_{1}^* + b p_{2}^* = 1 - \frac{1}{2(2 - b)} + b\left(\frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\right) = \frac{1}{2} \\] For firm 2: \\[ q_{2}^* = 1 - p_{2}^* + b p_{1}^* = 1 - \frac{1}{2(2 - b)} + b\left(\frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\right) = \frac{1}{2} \\] Thus, the Nash equilibrium outputs are \(q_{1}^* = q_{2}^* = \frac{1}{2}\).
05

Calculate companies' profits.

Since the firms have no costs, their profits are equal to their revenues. We can use the Nash equilibrium prices and outputs to calculate these profits. For firm 1: \\[ \pi_{1}^* = p_{1}^* q_{1}^* = \left(\frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\right) \left(\frac{1}{2}\right) = \frac{1}{4(2 - b)} \\] For firm 2: \\[ \pi_{2}^* = p_{2}^* q_{2}^* = \left(\frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\right) \left(\frac{1}{2}\right) = \frac{1}{4(2 - b)} \\] Thus, the Nash equilibrium profits are \(\pi_{1}^* = \pi_{2}^* = \frac{1}{4(2 - b)}\). #c. Representing the equilibrium on a diagram#
06

Sketch the Best-Response functions and equilibrium.

To represent the equilibrium on a diagram, we first need to draw the best-response functions of both firms. The best-response function for firm 1 is obtained by solving its first-order condition for \(p_1\): \\[ p_{1} = \frac{1 + b p_{2}}{2} \\] Similarly, the best-response function for firm 2 is obtained by solving its first-order condition for \(p_2\): \\[ p_{2} = \frac{1 + b p_{1}}{2} \\] First, sketch the best-response functions for both firms on a diagram, with \(p_1\) on the vertical axis and \(p_2\) on the horizontal axis. Label these functions as \(BR_1(p_2)\) and \(BR_2(p_1)\), respectively. Next, draw a representative isoprofit curve for firm 1. This curve will be upward-sloping and convex, reflecting the trade-off between raising its price to increase its profit margin and losing market share to its competitor. Finally, plot the Nash equilibrium values of \(p_1\) and \(p_2\) that we obtained in part (a). This point will be the intersection of the best-response functions and will lie on the representative isoprofit curve of firm 1.
07

Analyze the effect of an increase in \(b\).

Now we examine the effect of an increase in the differentiation parameter \(b\). Recall that the Nash equilibrium prices are given by \(p_{1}^* = p_{2}^* = \frac{1}{2(2 - b)}\). As \(b\) increases, the denominator of the Nash equilibrium prices shrinks, causing the prices to increase. In other words, an increase in \(b\) results in higher Nash equilibrium prices for both firms. On the diagram, this implies that the best-response functions of both firms will become steeper as \(b\) increases. This is because an increase in differentiation makes each firm less sensitive to the other firm's actions, allowing them to charge higher prices without losing too much market share. In summary, an increase in \(b\) leads to higher Nash equilibrium prices, steeper best-response functions, and a shift in the representative isoprofit curve for firm 1.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Nash equilibrium
In the world of economics, a Nash equilibrium is a situation where two or more players in a game reach a point where no player can benefit by changing their strategy while the others keep theirs unchanged. It's like a stalemate in chess where any move changes the balance.

In the context of a Bertrand game with differentiated products, two firms decide on prices for their products at the same time. Here, the Nash equilibrium occurs when each firm's price is the optimal response to the other firm's price. At this point, neither firm can unilaterally lower its price to increase profit without reducing both firms' overall profits.

Nash equilibrium stands as a critical concept because it involves strategic decision-making where each firm anticipates the competitor's move, adjusting its pricing strategy accordingly. Once equilibrium is reached, both firms settle on prices that balance competitive and cooperative interactions within the market.
best-response functions
Best-response functions are the strategies that maximize a player's payoff, given the other players' strategies in the game. Think of it as a guide to what each firm should do when they know the other firm's potential moves.

For example, in our Bertrand game situation, each firm derives a best-response function by considering the price set by the other firm. Each firm calculates how its profits are affected by its competitor's price. It then adjusts its price to maximize its profit.

The process involves setting the derivative of the profit function to zero to find the optimal price. The best-response functions are critical in deriving the Nash equilibrium because they show how each firm can optimize its decision-making in response to the competitor's pricing.

These functions are visually represented through diagrams, aiding in understanding how changes affect each player's strategies and lead to equilibrium.
differentiated products
Differentiated products are variations of goods that are similar but have differences making them perfect substitutes. Consider how different brands of cereal may look the same but have unique flavors or health benefits.

In a Bertrand game, the differentiation parameter \(b\) influences how much one firm's product can substitute for another's. This parameter is crucial to the firms' pricing decisions, as a higher \(b\) means more differentiation, reducing the direct price competition between firms.

Increased differentiation allows firms to charge higher prices because they don't compete solely on price. Customers may prefer one product over another due to unique features, like brand loyalty or quality, allowing firms flexibility in their pricing strategies. Overall, understanding product differentiation helps firms in predicting competitor behavior and setting competitive prices.
isoprofit curves
Isoprofit curves are plots that represent combinations of prices yielding the same profit for a firm. Imagine contour lines on a map that show elevation; here, they show profit levels instead.

Within Bertrand competition, an isoprofit curve for a firm gives a visual representation of how different pricing strategies across its product line yield the same profit. The curve typically slopes upwards: as one firm's price increases, the other firm's price should also increase to keep profits constant.

By illustrating these curves on a diagram, firms can visually grasp how changes in one firm's pricing affect the other's profits. Isoprofit curves provide strategic insights into pricing decisions, helping firms understand the profitability landscape of the market and better anticipating competitive responses. They shed light on not just single points of equilibrium but also potential paths to reach or deviate from them.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Assume as in Problem 15.1 that two firms with no production costs, facing demand \(Q=150-P\), choose quantities \(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\) a. Compute the subgame-perfect equilibrium of the Stackelberg version of the game in which firm 1 chooses \(q_{1}\) first and then firm 2 chooses \(q_{2}\) b. Now add an entry stage after firm 1 chooses \(q_{1}\). In this stage, firm 2 decides whether to enter. If it enters, then it must sink cost \(K_{2}\), after which it is allowed to choose \(q_{2}\). Compute the threshold value of \(K_{2}\) above which firm 1 prefers to deter firm \(2^{\prime}\) s entry c. Represent the Cournot, Stackelberg, and entry-deterrence outcomes on a best-response function diagram.

Hotelling's model of competition on a linear beach is used widely in many applications, but one application that is difficult to study in the model is free entry. Free entry is easiest to study in a model with symmetric firms, but more than two firms on a line cannot be symmetric because those located nearest the endpoints will have only one neighboring rival, whereas those located nearer the middle will have two. To avoid this problem, Steven Salop introduced competition on a circle. \(^{18}\) As in the Hotelling model, demanders are located at each point, and each demands one unit of the good. A consumer's surplus equals \(v\) (the value of consuming the good) minus the price paid for the good as well as the cost of having to travel to buy from the firm. Let this travel cost be \(t d\), where \(t\) is a parameter measuring how burdensome travel is and \(d\) is the distance traveled (note that we are here assuming a linear rather than a quadratic travel-cost function, in contrast to Example 15.5 . Initially, we take as given that there are \(n\) firms in the market and that each has the same cost function \(C_{i}=K+c q_{i}\) where \(K\) is the sunk cost required to enter the market [this will come into play in part (e) of the question, where we consider free entry] and \(c\) is the constant marginal cost of production. For simplicity, assume that the circumference of the circle equals 1 and that the \(n\) firms are located evenly around the circle at intervals of \(1 / n\). The \(n\) firms choose prices \(p_{i}\) simultancously. a. Each firm \(i\) is free to choose its own price \(\left(p_{i}\right)\) but is constrained by the price charged by its nearest neighbor to either side. Let \(p^{*}\) be the price these firms set in a symmetric equilibrium. Explain why the extent of any firm's market on either side \((x)\) is given by the equation $$p+t x=p^{*}+t[(1 / n)-x]$$ b. Given the pricing decision analyzed in part (a), firm \(i\) sells \(q_{i}=2 x\) because it has a market on both sides. Calculate the profit-maximizing price for this firm as a function of \(p^{*}, c, t,\) and \(n\) c. Noting that in a symmetric equilibrium all firms' prices will be equal to \(p^{*},\) show that \(p_{i}=p^{*}=c+t / n .\) Explain this result intuitively. d. Show that a firm's profits are \(t / n^{2}-K\) in equilibrium. e. What will the number of firms \(n^{*}\) be in long-run equilibrium in which firms can freely choose to enter? f. Calculate the socially optimal level of differentiation in this model, defined as the number of firms (and products) that minimizes the sum of production costs plus demander travel costs. Show that this number is precisely half the number calculated in part (e). Hence this model illustrates the possibility of overdifferentiation.

Use the first-order condition (Equation 15.2 ) for a Cournot firm to show that the usual inverse elasticity rule from Chapter 11 holds under Cournot competition (where the elasticity is associated with an individual firm's residual demand, the demand left after all rivals sell their output on the market). Manipulate Equation 15.2 in a different way to obtain an equivalent version of the inverse elasticity rule: \\[ \frac{P-M C}{P}=-\frac{s_{i}}{e_{Q, P}} \\] where \(s_{i}=q_{i} / Q\) is firm i's market share and \(e_{Q, p}\) is the elasticity of market demand. Compare this version of the inverse elasticity rule with that for a monopolist from the previous chapter.

This question will explore signaling when entry deterrence is impossible; thus, the signaling firm accommodates its rival's entry. Assume deterrence is impossible because the two firms do not pay a sunk cost to enter or remain in the market. The setup of the model will follow Example \(15.4,\) so the calculations there will aid the solution of this problem. In particular, firm \(i\) 's demand is given by $$q_{i}=a_{i}-p_{i}+\frac{p_{j}}{2}$$ where \(a_{i}\) is product \(i\) 's attribute (say, quality). Production is costless. Firm 1's attribute can be one of two values: either \(a_{1}=1\) in which case we say firm 1 is the low type, or \(a_{1}=2,\) in which case we say it is the high type. Assume there is no discounting across periods for simplicity. a. Compute the Nash equilibrium of the game of complete information in which firm 1 is the high type and firm 2 knows that firm 1 is the high type. b. Compute the Nash equilibrium of the game in which firm 1 is the low type and firm 2 knows that firm 1 is the low type. c. Solve for the Bayesian-Nash equilibrium of the game of incomplete information in which firm 1 can be either type with equal probability. Firm 1 knows its type, but firm 2 only knows the probabilities. Because we did not spend time this chapter on Bayesian games, you may want to consult Chapter 8 (especially Example 8.7 ). d. Which of firm 1 's types gains from incomplete information? Which type would prefer complete information (and thus would have an incentive to signal its type if possible)? Does firm 2 earn more profit on average under complete information or under incomplete information? e. Consider a signaling variant of the model chat has two periods. Firms 1 and 2 choose prices in the first period, when firm 2 has incomplete information about firm 1 's type. Firm 2 observes firm 1 's price in this period and uses the information to update its beliefs about firm 1's type. Then firms engage in another period of price competition. Show that there is a separating equilibrium in which each type of firm 1 charges the same prices as computed in part (d). You may assume that, if firm 1 chooses an out-of-equilibrium price in the first period, then firm 2 believes that firm 1 is the low type with probability 1 . Hint: To prove the existence of a separating equilibrium, show that the loss to the low type from trying to pool in the first period exceeds the second-period gain from having convinced firm 2 that it is the high type. Use your answers from parts (a)-(d) where possible to aid in your solution.

Assume for simplicity that a monopolist has no costs of production and faces a demand curve given by \(Q=150-P\) a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for this monopolist. Also calculate the monopolist's profit. b. Suppose instead that there are two firms in the market facing the demand and cost conditions just described for their identical products. Firms choose quantities simultaneously as in the Cournot model. Compute the outputs in the Nash equilibrium. Also compute market output, price, and firm profits. c. Suppose the two firms choose prices simultaneously as in the Bertrand model. Compute the prices in the Nash equilibrium. Also compute firm output and profit as well as market output. d. Graph the demand curve and indicate where the market price-quantity combinations from parts (a)-(c) appear on the curve.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free