Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

A monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \(A C=M C=5 .\) The firm faces a market demand curve given by \(Q=53-P\). a. Calculate the profit-maximizing price-quantity combination for the monopolist. Also calculate the monopolist's profits. b. What output level would be produced by this industry under perfect competition (where price \(=\) marginal cost)? c. Calculate the consumer surplus obtained by consumers in case (b). Show that this exceeds the sum of the monopolist's profits and the consumer surplus received in case (a). What is the value of the "deadweight loss" from monopolization?

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: The deadweight loss resulting from monopolization in this scenario is 288.

Step by step solution

01

Identify the Profit-maximizing Quantity

To maximize profits, monopolists set MR=MC. First, we need to find the inverse demand curve, P = 53 - Q. Next, we compute the total revenue function, TR = P * Q = (53-Q) * Q. Finally, we find the marginal revenue function, MR, by taking the derivative of the total revenue function with respect to Q. MR = d(TR)/dQ = d[(53-Q)*Q]/dQ Now we can find the profit-maximizing quantity by setting MR = MC = 5.
02

Solve for the Profit-maximizing Quantity

We have the marginal revenue function: MR = d[(53-Q)*Q]/dQ Calculate the derivative: MR = d(53Q - Q^2)/dQ = 53 - 2Q Set MR = MC: 53 - 2Q = 5 Rearrange and solve for Q: 2Q = 48 Q = 24 The profit-maximizing quantity for the monopolist is Q = 24.
03

Find the Profit-maximizing Price

Now that we have the profit-maximizing quantity, we can find the profit-maximizing price by plugging the quantity into the inverse demand curve: P = 53 - Q P = 53 - 24 P = 29 The profit-maximizing price is P = 29.
04

Calculate the Monopolist's Profits

Profits can be calculated by the following formula: Profit = (P - MC) * Q Plug in the values for P, MC, and Q: Profit = (29 - 5) * 24 Profit = 24 * 24 Profit = 576 The monopolist's profits are 576.
05

Output level under Perfect Competition

Under perfect competition, price is equal to marginal cost, so: P = MC P = 5 Now, plug P into the inverse demand curve and solve for Q: 5 = 53 - Q Q = 53 - 5 Q = 48 Under perfect competition, the output level would be Q = 48.
06

Calculate Consumer Surplus in case (b)

Consumer surplus can be calculated as: Consumer Surplus = 0.5 * (P_max - P) * Q Where P_max is the price when quantity is zero (demand curve intercept), P is the equilibrium price under perfect competition (already found to be 5), and Q is the quantity produced under perfect competition (already found to be 48). In our case, P_max = 53. Consumer Surplus = 0.5 * (53 - 5) * 48 Consumer Surplus = 0.5 * 48 * 48 Consumer Surplus = 1152
07

Calculate Deadweight Loss

First, calculate the consumer surplus in case (a) (monopoly): Consumer Surplus_a = 0.5 * (53 - 29) * 24 Consumer Surplus_a = 0.5 * 24 * 24 Consumer Surplus_a = 288 Now, we can calculate the deadweight loss, which is the difference between the sum of monopolist's profits and consumer surplus in case (a) and the consumer surplus in case (b): Deadweight Loss = Consumer Surplus_b - (Consumer Surplus_a + Monopolist's Profits) Deadweight Loss = 1152 - (288 + 576) Deadweight Loss = 1152 - 864 Deadweight Loss = 288 The value of deadweight loss from monopolization is 288.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Profit-Maximizing Quantity and Price
In a monopoly market structure, where a single firm dominates the market, determining the profit-maximizing quantity and price is crucial for the monopolist. Unlike firms in a perfectly competitive market that take the market price as given, a monopolist has the power to set its price.

To find the profit-maximizing output, the monopolist equates marginal revenue (MR) with marginal cost (MC). The demand curve faced by the monopolist is downward sloping, so its MR curve lies below the demand curve due to the diminishing marginal revenue with each additional unit sold. After computing the MR, the firm equates it to MC, which remains constant in our case at $5, to find the quantity that maximizes profit.

Once the optimal quantity is identified, the monopolist uses the demand curve to determine the price consumers are willing to pay for that quantity. The result is a price that is typically higher and an output that is lower than what would be observed in a perfectly competitive market, leading to higher profits for the firm but also potential inefficiencies in the market.
Perfect Competition Equilibrium
Under perfect competition, the market consists of many small firms, each with no control over the price. These firms are price takers, which means they accept the market equilibrium price where supply equals demand. In this scenario, the firm’s marginal cost (MC) curve is its supply curve.

The equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market is where the aggregate demand intersects with the aggregate supply, implying that the equilibrium price equals MC. In our exercise, if this industry were perfectly competitive, the equilibrium output would be determined by setting the price equal to MC. The output would be twice as much as the monopolist's profit-maximizing quantity, demonstrating the monopolist's power to restrict output and elevate prices above efficient levels.
Consumer Surplus
Consumer surplus is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good or service and what they actually pay. It represents the economic benefit that consumers receive when they are able to purchase a product for less than the highest price they are willing to pay.

In the context of perfect competition, consumer surplus is maximized because the price equals MC, allowing the market to produce and sell as much as consumers are willing to consume at that price. This leads to an allocation of resources that satisfies consumer preferences to the greatest extent. The exercise demonstrates how consumer surplus in a competitive market exceeds the total surplus in a monopolistic market, emphasizing the loss of welfare due to monopolistic practices.
Deadweight Loss
Deadweight loss refers to the loss of economic efficiency when the equilibrium in a market is not achieved or is not achievable. In a monopoly, the deadweight loss occurs because the monopolist sets a higher price and produces fewer goods than in a perfectly competitive market. This not only reduces consumer surplus but also prevents some transactions that would have occurred if the market were competitive.

The exercise illustrates that monopolization leads to a value of deadweight loss, calculated as the difference between the higher consumer surplus in a competitive market and the sum of the monopolist's profit plus consumer surplus under monopoly. This loss is a cost to society because it represents foregone trades—transactions that could have benefitted both consumers and producers that did not happen due to the monopolist's pricing and output decisions.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

A monopolist faces a market demand curve given by \\[Q=70-p.\\] a. If the monopolist can produce at constant average and marginal costs of \(A C=M C=6,\) what output level will the monopolist choose to maximize profits? What is the price at this output level? What are the monopolist's profits? b. Assume instead that the monopolist has a cost structure where total costs are described by \\[C(Q)=0.25 Q^{2}-5 Q+300.\\] With the monopolist facing the same market demand and marginal revenue, what price-quantity combination will be chosen now to maximize profits? What will profits be? c. Assume now that a third cost structure explains the monopolist's position, with total costs given by \\[C(Q)=0.0133 Q^{3}-5 Q+250.\\] Again, calculate the monopolist's price-quantity combination that maximizes profits. What will profit be? Hint: Set \(M C=\) \(M R\) as usual and use the quadratic formula to solve the second-order equation for \(Q\) d. Graph the market demand curve, the \(M R\) curve, and the three marginal cost curves from parts (a), (b), and (c). Notice that the monopolist's profit- making ability is constrained by (1) the market demand curve (along with its associated \(M R\) curve) and (2) the cost structure underlying production.

Suppose a monopolist produces alkaline batteries that may have various useful lifetimes \((X) .\) Suppose also that consumers (inverse) demand depends on batteries' lifetimes and quantity (Q) purchased according to the function \\[P(Q, X)=g(X \cdot Q),\\] where \(g^{\prime} < 0 .\) That is, consumers care only about the product of quantity times lifetime: They are willing to pay equally for many short-lived batteries or few long-lived ones. Assume also that battery costs are given by \\[C(Q, X)=C(X) Q,\\] where \(C^{\prime}(X) > 0 .\) Show that, in this case, the monopoly will opt for the same level of \(X\) as does a competitive industry even though levels of output and prices may differ. Explain your result. Hint: Treat \(X Q\) as a composite commodity.

Suppose the market for Hula Hoops is monopolized by a single firm. a. Draw the initial equilibrium for such a market. b. Now suppose the demand for Hula Hoops shifts outward slightly. Show that, in general (contrary to the competitive case), it will not be possible to predict the effect of this shift in demand on the market price of Hula Hoops. c. Consider three possible ways in which the price elasticity of demand might change as the demand curve shifts: It might increase, it might decrease, or it might stay the same. Consider also that marginal costs for the monopolist might be increasing, decreasing, or constant in the range where \(M R=M C\). Consequently, there are nine different combinations of types of demand shifts and marginal cost slope configurations. Analyze each of these to determine for which it is possible to make a definite prediction about the effect of the shift in demand on the price of Hula Hoops.

Suppose a monopoly market has a demand function in which quantity demanded depends not only on market price (P) but also on the amount of advertising the firm does ( \(A\), measured in dollars). The specific form of this function is \\[Q=(20-P)\left(1+0.1 A-0.01 A^{2}\right).\\] The monopolistic firm's cost function is given by \\[C=10 Q+15+A.\\] a. Suppose there is no advertising \((A=0) .\) What output will the profit- maximizing firm choose? What market price will this yield? What will be the monopoly's profits? b. Now let the firm also choose its optimal level of advertising expenditure. In this situation, what output level will be chosen? What price will this yield? What will the level of advertising be? What are the firm's profits in this case? Hint: This can be worked out most easily by assuming the monopoly chooses the profit-maximizing price rather than quantity.

An alternative way to study the welfare properties of a monopolist's choices is to assume the existence of a utility function for the customers of the monopoly of the form utility \(=U(Q, X),\) where \(Q\) is quantity consumed and \(X\) is the quality associated with that quantity. A social planner's problem then would be to choose \(Q\) and \(X\) to maximize social welfare as represented by \(S W=U(Q, X)-C(Q, X)\). a. What are the first-order conditions for a welfare maximum? b. The monopolist's goal is to choose the \(Q\) and \(X\) that maximize \(\pi=P(Q, X) \cdot Q-C(Q, X) .\) What are the first-order conditions for this maximization? c. Use your results from parts (a) and (b) to show that, at the monopolist's preferred choices, \(\partial S W / \partial Q>0\). That is, as we have already shown, prove that social welfare would be improved if more were produced. Hint: Assume that \(\partial U / \partial Q=P\) d. Show that, at the monopolist's preferred choices, the sign of \(\partial S W / \partial X\) is ambiguous-that is, it cannot be determined (on the sole basis of the general theory of monopoly) whether the monopolist produces either too much or too little quality.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free