Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

In the country of Ruritania there are two regions, \(A\) and \(B\). Two goods \((x \text { and } y)\) are produced in both regions. Production functions for region \(A\) are given by \\[ \begin{array}{l} x_{A}=\sqrt{l_{x}} \\ y_{A}=\sqrt{l_{y}} \end{array} \\] here \(l_{x}\) and \(l_{y}\) are the quantities of labor devoted to \(x\) and \(y\) production, respectively. Total labor available in region \(A\) is 100 units; that is, \\[ l_{x}+l_{y}=100 \\] Using a similar notation for region \(B\), production functions are given by \\[ \begin{array}{l} x_{B}=\frac{1}{2} \sqrt{l_{x}} \\ y_{B}=\frac{1}{2} \sqrt{l_{y}} \end{array} \\] There are also 100 units of labor available in region \(B\) ? \\[ l_{x}+l_{y}=100 \\] a. Calculate the production possibility curves for regions \(A\) and \(B\). b. What condition must hold if production in Ruritania is to be allocated efficiently between regions \(A\) and \(B\) (assuming labor cannot move from one region to the other \() ?\) c. Calculate the production possibility curve for Ruritania (again assuming labor is immobile between regions). How much total \(y\) can Ruritania produce if total \(x\) output is \(12 ?\) Hint: \(\mathrm{A}\) graphical analysis may be of some help here.

Short Answer

Expert verified
The total amount of good y that Ruritania can produce if it's producing 12 units of good x is 9 units.

Step by step solution

01

Production Possibility Curve for Region A

To find the production possibility curve for region A, we'll use the given production functions and the constraint on labor availability. \[ x_A = \sqrt{l_x} \] \[ y_A = \sqrt{l_y} \] Given that the total labor available in region A is 100 units, we have: \[ l_x + l_y = 100 \] Solve the labor constraint for one of the variables, for example, \(l_y = 100 - l_x\). Then substitute this into the \(y_A\) equation: \[y_A = \sqrt{100 - l_x}\] The production possibility curve for region A is given by: \[ y_A = \sqrt{100 - l_x} \]
02

Production Possibility Curve for Region B

Similarly, to find the production possibility curve for region B, we'll use the given production functions and the constraint on labor availability. \[ x_B = \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{l_x} \] \[ y_B = \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{l_y} \] Given that the total labor available in region B is 100 units, we have: \[ l_x + l_y = 100 \] Solve the labor constraint for one of the variables, for example, \(l_y = 100 - l_x\). Then substitute this into the \(y_B\) equation: \[ y_B = \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{100 - l_x} \] The production possibility curve for region B is given by: \[ y_B = \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{100 - l_x} \]
03

The Condition for Efficient Production Allocation

For efficient production allocation between region A and B, given that labor is immobile, the marginal rate of transformation must be equal in both regions. The Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT) for a good can be defined as the rate at which a good can be transformed into another good with the available resources. It can be expressed as the negative relationship between the production functions of the two goods. For region A, MRT_A = \(- \frac{dy_A}{dx_A} = - \frac{0.5}{\sqrt{100 - l_x}}\) For region B, MRT_B = \(- \frac{dy_B}{dx_B} = - \frac{1}{\sqrt{100 - l_x}}\) For efficient production allocation, MRT_A = MRT_B. \[ - \frac{0.5}{\sqrt{100 - l_x}} = - \frac{1}{\sqrt{100 - l_x}} \]
04

Production Possibility Curve for Ruritania

To find the production possibility curve for Ruritania, we need to sum the production functions of region A and region B for each good. Let \(x_T = x_A + x_B\) and \(y_T = y_A + y_B\). Note that when \(x_T = 12\), we need to determine \(y_T\). Though graphical analysis can be a quick method, we can also find the result by solving for \(l_{x_A}\) and \(l_{x_B}\). \(x_A = \sqrt{l_{x_A}} = 12 - \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{l_{x_B}}\) (since \(x_T = x_A + x_B\)) Squaring both sides: \(l_{x_A} = 144 - 12\sqrt{l_{x_B}} + \frac{1}{4}l_{x_B}\) Now we have two labor constraints: \(l_{x_A} + l_{y_A} = 100\) \(l_{x_B} + l_{y_B} = 100\) Substituting \(l_{x_A}\) from the equation above and the labor constraints: \(144 - 12\sqrt{l_{x_B}} + \frac{1}{4}l_{x_B} + l_{y_A} = 100\) We now have two equations and two unknowns (\(l_{x_B}\) and \(l_{y_A}\)): \(l_{y_A} = 100 - l_{x_A}\) \(l_{y_A} = 56 + 12\sqrt{l_{x_B}} - \frac{1}{4}l_{x_B}\) Solving these two equations, we get: \(l_{x_B} = 64\) \(l_{y_A} = 36\) Now, we can find the total \(y\) production for Ruritania, \(y_T\): \(y_T = y_A + y_B = \sqrt{100 - l_{x_A}} + \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{100 - l_{x_B}}\) Substitute the values of \(l_{x_A}\) and \(l_{x_B}\): \(y_T = \sqrt{36} + \frac{1}{2}\sqrt{36} = 6 + 3 = 9\) So Ruritania can produce a total of 9 units of \(y\) if total \(x\) output is 12, assuming labor is immobile between regions.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT)
The Marginal Rate of Transformation (MRT) is a fundamental concept in microeconomics, representing the rate at which one good can be substituted for another in production while keeping total output constant. It reflects the trade-offs and costs of opportunity intrinsic to resource allocation. Understanding MRT is crucial for analyzing how economies adjust outputs of various goods based on available resources and technology.

In the context of the exercise from Ruritania, determining the MRT for both regions A and B allows us to understand how labor resources are allocated between producing good x and good y. Intuitively, it’s about how much of good y you must give up to produce an additional unit of good x, holding total labor constant. It's a measure of the slope of the production possibility curve at any given point, which in a sense, maps the 'price' of transforming one good into another within a specific region.
Efficient Production Allocation
Efficient production allocation is reached when resources are distributed in a way that it’s not possible to produce more of one good without producing less of another, also known as the point of productive efficiency. At this point, the economy operates on its production possibility curve, and the marginal rates of transformation across regions or segments equalize.

For Ruritania's two regions, achieving efficient production allocation means equating MRTs in both regions. This ensures that the cost of opportunity for producing goods x and y is the same, preventing resources from being misallocated. When resources (like labor in our problem) are limited, efficient allocation is key for maximizing the overall production and thus, welfare within the economy.
Labor Constraint
In the context of microeconomic theory, a labor constraint refers to the finite amount of labor resources available for producing goods and services. This constraint limits the maximum possible outputs, shaping the production possibility curve for an economy or region.

In the Ruritania example, both regions A and B have a labor constraint of 100 units each, which confines the production capacities for goods x and y. As labor cannot be transferred between regions, it's essential for Ruritania to allocate this scarce resource efficiently to maximize output. By understanding and applying the labor constraint equation, producers and planners can identify the feasible combinations of Good x and y each region can produce, significantly impacting their overall economic planning and strategy.
Microeconomic Theory
Microeconomic theory is the branch of economics that focuses on the behaviors of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of limited resources. It encompasses various principles, like demand and supply, elasticity, marginal utility, and the production possibility frontier, which are essential in determining how economies function at the fundamental level.

The exercise about Ruritania incorporates principles of microeconomic theory by evaluating how regions with specific constraints allocate labor to produce different goods efficiently. The production possibility curves, MRT, and labor constraints are all rooted in microeconomic theory, helping us to understand the basic choices that underpin the broader economic system. By grasping these principles, students can better understand how optimal decisions are made in the face of scarcity, which is the essential problem that economics seeks to address.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Consider an economy with just one technique available for the production of each good. \\[ \begin{array}{lcc} \text { Good } & \text { Food } & \text { Cloth } \\ \hline \text { Labor per unit output } & 1 & 1 \\ \text { Land per unit output } & 2 & 1 \\ \hline \end{array} \\] a. Suppose land is unlimited but labor equals 100 . Write and sketch the production possibility fronticr. b. Suppose labor is unlimited but land equals \(150 .\) Write and sketch the production possibility frontier. c. Suppose labor equals 100 and land equals \(150 .\) Write and sketch the production possibility frontier. Hint: What are the intercepts of the production possibility frontier? When is land fully employed? Labor? Both? Explain why the production possibility frontier of part (c) is concave. e. Sketch the relative price of food as a function of its output in part (c). f. If consumers insist on trading 4 units of food for 5 units of cloth, what is the relative price of food? Why? g. Explain why production is exactly the same at a price ratio of \(p_{F} / p_{C}=1.1\) as at \(p_{F} / p_{C}=1.9\) h. Suppose that capital is also required for producing food and clothing and that capital requirements per unit of food and per unit of clothing are 0.8 and \(0.9,\) respectively. There are 100 units of capital available. What is the production possibility curve in this case? Answer part (e) for this case.

In Example 13.3 we showed how a Pareto efficiency exchange equilibrium can be described as the solution to a constrained maximum problem, In this problem we provide a similar illustration for an economy involving production. Suppose that there is only one person in a two-good economy and that his or her utility function is given by \(U(x, y)\). Suppose also that this economy's production possibility frontier can be written in implicit form as \(T(x, y)=0\) a. What is the constrained optimization problem that this economy will seek to solve if it wishes to make the best use of its available resources? b. What are the first-order conditions for a maximum in this situation? c. How would the efficient situation described in part (b) be brought about by a perfectly competitive system in which this individual maximizes utility and the firms underlying the production possibility frontier maximize profits. d. Under what situations might the first-order conditions described in part (b) not yield a utility maximum?

The construction of the production possibility curve shown in Figures 13.2 and 13.3 can be used to illustrate three important "theorems" in international trade theory. To get started, notice in Figure 13.2 that the efficiency line \(O_{x}, O_{y}\) is bowed above the main diagonal of the Edgeworth box. This shows that the production of good \(x\) is always "capital intensive" relative to the production of good \(y\). That is, when production is efficient, \(\left(\frac{5}{7}\right)_{x}>\left(\frac{5}{1}\right)\), no matter how much of the goods are produced. Demonstration of the trade theorems assumes that the price ratio, \(p=p_{x} / p_{y}\) is determined in international markets-the domestic economy must adjust to this ratio (in trade jargon, the country under examination is assumed to be "a small country in a large world"). a Factor price equalization theorem: Use Figure 13.4 to show how the international price ratio, \(p\), determines the point in the Edgeworth box at which domestic production will take place. Show how this determines the factor price ratio, \(w / v\). If production functions are the same throughout the world, what will this imply about relative factor prices throughout the world? b. Stolper-Samuelson theorem: An increase in \(p\) will cause the production to move clockwise along the production possibility frontier \(-x\) production will increase and \(y\) production will decrease. Use the Edgeworth box diagram to show that such a move will decrease \(k / l\) in the production of both goods. Explain why this will cause \(w / v\) to decrease. What are the implications of this for the opening of trade relations (which typically increases the price of the good produced intensively with a country's most abundant input). c. Rybczynski theorem: Suppose again that \(p\) is set by external markets and does not change. Show that an increase in \(k\) will increase the output of \(x\) (the capital-intensive good) and reduce the output of \(y\) (the labor-intensive good).

Suppose there are only three goods \(\left(x_{1}, x_{2}, x_{3}\right)\) in an economy and that the excess demand functions for \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3}\) are given by \\[ \begin{array}{l} E D_{2}=-\frac{3 p_{2}}{p_{1}}+\frac{2 p_{3}}{p_{1}}-1 \\ E D_{3}=-\frac{4 p_{2}}{p_{1}}-\frac{2 p_{3}}{p_{1}}-2 \end{array} \\] a Show that these functions are homogencous of degree 0 in \(p_{1}, p_{2},\) and \(p_{3}\) b. Use Walras' law to show that, if \(E D_{2}=E D_{3}=0,\) then \(E D_{1}\) must also be \(0 .\) Can you also use Walras' law to calculate \(E D_{1} ?\) c. Solve this system of equations for the equilibrium relative prices \(p_{2} / p_{1}\) and \(p_{3} / p_{1}\). What is the equilibrium value for \(p_{3} / p_{2} ?\)

Smith and Jones are stranded on a desert island. Each has in his possession some slices of ham \((H)\) and cheese (C). Smith is a choosy eater and will eat ham and cheese only in the fixed proportions of 2 slices of cheese to 1 slice of ham. His utility function is given by \(U_{s}=\min (H, C / 2)\) Jones is more flexible in his dietary tastes and has a utility function given by \(U_{j}=4 H+3 C\). Total endowments are 100 slices of ham and 200 slices of cheese. a. Draw the Edgeworth box diagram that represents the possibilitics for exchange in this situation. What is the only exchange ratio that can prevail in any equilibrium? b. Suppose Smith initially had \(40 \mathrm{H}\) and \(80 \mathrm{C}\). What would the equilibrium position be? c. Suppose Smith initially had \(60 H\) and \(80 C\). What would the equilibrium position be? d. Suppose Smith (much the stronger of the two) decides not to play by the rules of the game. Then what could the final equilibrium position be?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free