Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Suppose that Robinson Crusoe produces and consumes fish ( F ) and coconuts (C). Assume that, during a certain period, he has decided to work 200 hours and is indifferent as to whether he spends this time fishing or gathering coconuts. Robinson's production for fish is given by \[ F=\sqrt{I_{F}} \] and for coconuts by \[ C=\sqrt{I_{C}} \] where lF and lC are the number of hours spent fishing or gathering coconuts. Consequently, \[ l_{c}+l_{F}=200 \] Robinson Crusoe's utility for fish and coconuts is given by \[ \text { utility }=\sqrt{F \cdot C} \] a. If Robinson cannot trade with the rest of the world, how will he choose to allocate his labor? What will the optimal levels of F and C be? What will his utility be? What will be the RPT (of fish for coconuts)? b. Suppose now that trade is opened and Robinson can trade fish and coconuts at a price ratio of pF/PC=2/1. If Robinson continues to produce the quantities of F and C from part (a), what will he choose to consume once given the opportunity to trade? What will his new level of utility be? c. How would your answer to part (b) change if Robinson adjusts his production to take advantage of the world prices? d. Graph your results for parts (a), (b), and (c).

Short Answer

Expert verified
Additionally, what are the relative price and utility levels? Answer: In autarky, the optimal labor allocations, production, and consumption levels for Robinson are found by optimizing his utility function given the constraints, production functions, and labor constraint. With these optimal levels, we can calculate Robinson's utility and the relative price of fish and coconuts using the RPT.

Step by step solution

01

Part A: Optimal Labor Allocation, Production, and Utility in Autarky

Given the utility function, production functions, and labor constraint, we will first set up a Lagrangian function to optimize Robinson's utility. The Lagrangian is: \[ \mathcal{L}=\sqrt{F \cdot C} + \lambda \left(200-l_F-l_C\right) \] where the constraint is lF+lC=200. To optimize the utility, we will take the partial derivatives with respect to F, C, lF, and lC, and the Lagrange multiplier λ. We will then set these derivatives equal to zero and solve the resulting system of equations to get the optimal labor allocations and optimal levels of F and C. After finding the optimal labor allocation, we can plug this into the production functions to get the optimal levels of F and C. Finally, we will calculate Robinson's utility using the utility function and the Relative Price of Trade (RPT) between fish and coconuts.
02

Part B: Consumption Decisions with Trade

Now that trade is allowed, Robinson can buy and sell fish and coconuts at the price ratio of pF/pC=2/1. Assuming he continues to produce the same amounts of F and C, we will use the price ratio and his production quantities to find out his optimal consumption bundle. To do this, we can apply the budget constraint, as well as the utility function. Finally, we will calculate Robinson's new level of utility based on this new consumption decision.
03

Part C: Production Changes with World Prices

In this part, we are asked to analyze how Robinson changes his production strategy in response to the world prices for fish and coconuts. To find the new optimal production levels, we will have to set up another optimization problem, this time taking the world prices into account. Once we find the new optimal production levels under world prices, we can then calculate the new consumption decision and Robinson's utility.
04

Part D: Graphical Analysis

Now that we have the results from all previous parts (a), (b), and (c), we can create a graph to visualize Robinson's labor allocation, production, and consumption decisions under autarky, trade with no production adjustment, and trade with production adjustment. On this graph, we will plot the production and consumption possibilities frontiers, as well as the utility levels for each scenario.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Utility Maximization
In microeconomic theory, utility maximization refers to the idea that individuals choose to allocate their resources in a manner that maximizes their satisfaction or happiness, often termed 'utility'. This is a fundamental proposition in microeconomics and consumer theory.

Considering our castaway, Robinson Crusoe, he faces a decision on how to allocate his time—his most valuable resource—between fishing and gathering coconuts. His utility, as given by the equation utility=FC, is maximized when the amount of labor he devotes to each activity produces the optimal combination of fish (F) and coconuts (C) that will give him the highest possible satisfaction.

To solve for this, economists use Lagrangian multipliers in a constrained optimization problem where the utility function is subject to a time constraint. As illustrated in the step-by-step solution, by taking partial derivatives and setting them equal to zero, Robinson can determine the optimal allocation of his labor that maximizes his utility. This approach encapsulates the very essence of the utility maximization problem - allocating resources efficiently within given constraints.
Production Functions
Production functions are mathematical equations that describe the relationship between inputs and outputs in the production process. For Robinson Crusoe, his production functions for fish and coconuts are expressed as F=IF and C=IC, with IF and IC representing the time spent fishing and gathering, respectively.

The shape of the production functions implies that increases in labor hours contribute to greater output, but at a decreasing rate due to the square root, showcasing the principle of diminishing marginal returns. In the given exercise, the production functions also hold the key to unlocking how Robinson will allocate his time to achieve the levels of output that will maximize his utility, given the restriction of his 200 available hours.

Understanding the properties of production functions, such as returns to scale and elasticity of substitution, is critical when it comes to analyzing and predicting the behavior of producers, both in theoretical models and real-world scenarios.
Trade and Consumption
When analyzing trade and consumption, economists examine how the ability to trade affects an individual's or a country's consumption choices. Before trade, individuals or countries consume what they produce. Upon opening to trade, they can specialize in producing goods in which they have a comparative advantage and then trade for other desired goods, potentially increasing overall utility.

For Robinson, the opening of trade allows him to exchange fish for coconuts (or vice versa) at world prices, altering his consumption bundle. In the exercise, the pre-trade conditions—also known as autarky—limit him to his production possibilities. With trade, he can now consume beyond these limitations, as illustrated in step 2 of the solution by applying the price ratio or the terms of trade.

Understanding trade and consumption involves dissecting the effects of relative prices and budget constraints on an individual's or a nation's consumption patterns, a pivotal component in international economics and individual decision making.
Relative Price of Trade (RPT)
The concept of the Relative Price of Trade (RPT) is significant in microeconomics, especially when discussing trade. It represents the rate at which a person can trade one good for another in the market. In Robinson Crusoe's case, the RPT is the rate at which he can trade fish for coconuts or vice versa.

In the original exercise, before trade, the internal RPT for Robinson is determined by the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) derived from his utility function, reflecting his personal valuations of fish in terms of coconuts. After opening to trade, the external RPT is dictated by the world prices, which in the exercise is given as pF/PC=2/1, meaning that one coconut can trade for two fish.

The RPT is a crucial component for understanding how trade can lead to utility maximization. When the external RPT is more favorable than the internal RPT, individuals like Robinson can gain from trade by adjusting their production and consumption according to the world prices, as detailed in part C of the solution. Analyzing the RPT helps explain and predict not only individual behavior but also the patterns of trade flows between countries.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose two individuals (Smith and Jones) each have 10 hours of labor to devote to producing either ice cream (x) or chicken soup (y). Smith's utility function is given by \[ U_{s}=x^{0.3} y^{07} \] whereas Jones" is given by \[ U_{I}=x^{0.5} y^{0.5} \] The individuals do not care whether they produce x or y, and the production function for each good is given by \[ x=2 l \text { and } y=3 l \] where l is the total labor devoted to production of each good. a. What must the price ratio, px/py be? b. Given this price ratio, how much x and y will Smith and Jones demand? Hint: Set the wage equal to 1 here. c. How should labor be allocated between x and y to satisfy the demand calculated in part (b)?

Suppose the production possibility frontier for guns (x) and butter (y) is given by \[ x^{2}+2 y^{2}=900 \] a. Graph this frontier. b. If individuals always prefer consumption bundles in which y=2x, how much x and y will be produced? c. At the point described in part (b), what will be the RPT and hence what price ratio will cause production to take place at that point? (This slope should be approximated by considering small changes in x and y around the optimal point.) d. Show your solution on the figure from part (a).

Suppose there are only three goods (x1,x2,x3) in an economy and that the excess demand functions for x2 and x3 are given by \[ ED2=3p2p1+2p3p11ED3=4p2p12p3p12 \] a Show that these functions are homogencous of degree 0 in p1,p2, and p3 b. Use Walras' law to show that, if ED2=ED3=0, then ED1 must also be 0. Can you also use Walras' law to calculate ED1? c. Solve this system of equations for the equilibrium relative prices p2/p1 and p3/p1. What is the equilibrium value for p3/p2?

Smith and Jones are stranded on a desert island. Each has in his possession some slices of ham (H) and cheese (C). Smith is a choosy eater and will eat ham and cheese only in the fixed proportions of 2 slices of cheese to 1 slice of ham. His utility function is given by Us=min(H,C/2) Jones is more flexible in his dietary tastes and has a utility function given by Uj=4H+3C. Total endowments are 100 slices of ham and 200 slices of cheese. a. Draw the Edgeworth box diagram that represents the possibilitics for exchange in this situation. What is the only exchange ratio that can prevail in any equilibrium? b. Suppose Smith initially had 40H and 80C. What would the equilibrium position be? c. Suppose Smith initially had 60H and 80C. What would the equilibrium position be? d. Suppose Smith (much the stronger of the two) decides not to play by the rules of the game. Then what could the final equilibrium position be?

The construction of the production possibility curve shown in Figures 13.2 and 13.3 can be used to illustrate three important "theorems" in international trade theory. To get started, notice in Figure 13.2 that the efficiency line Ox,Oy is bowed above the main diagonal of the Edgeworth box. This shows that the production of good x is always "capital intensive" relative to the production of good y. That is, when production is efficient, (57)x>(51), no matter how much of the goods are produced. Demonstration of the trade theorems assumes that the price ratio, p=px/py is determined in international markets-the domestic economy must adjust to this ratio (in trade jargon, the country under examination is assumed to be "a small country in a large world"). a Factor price equalization theorem: Use Figure 13.4 to show how the international price ratio, p, determines the point in the Edgeworth box at which domestic production will take place. Show how this determines the factor price ratio, w/v. If production functions are the same throughout the world, what will this imply about relative factor prices throughout the world? b. Stolper-Samuelson theorem: An increase in p will cause the production to move clockwise along the production possibility frontier x production will increase and y production will decrease. Use the Edgeworth box diagram to show that such a move will decrease k/l in the production of both goods. Explain why this will cause w/v to decrease. What are the implications of this for the opening of trade relations (which typically increases the price of the good produced intensively with a country's most abundant input). c. Rybczynski theorem: Suppose again that p is set by external markets and does not change. Show that an increase in k will increase the output of x (the capital-intensive good) and reduce the output of y (the labor-intensive good).

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free