Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The domestic demand for portable radios is given by $$Q=5,000-100 \mathrm{P}$$ where price \(\mathrm{(P)}\) is measured in dollars and quantity \(\mathrm{(Q)}\) is measured in thousands of radios per year. The domestic supply curve for radios is given by $$Q=150 \mathrm{P}$$ a. What is the domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market? b. Suppose portable radios can be imported at a world price of $$\$ 10$$ per radio. If trade were unencumbered, what would the new market equilibrium be? How many portable radios would be imported? c. If domestic portable radio producers succeeded in having a $$\$ 5$$ tariff implemented, how would this change the market equilibrium? How much would be collected in tariff revenues? How much consumer surplus would be transferred to domestic producers? What would the deadweight loss from the tariff be? d. How would your results from part (c) be changed if the government reached an agreement with foreign suppliers to "voluntarily" limit the portable radios they export to \(1,250,000\) per year? Explain how this differs from the case of a tariff.

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary, the domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market is initially P=$20 and Q=3,000 radios per year. With free trade, the market equilibrium shifts to P=$10 and Q=4,000 radios per year, with 2,500 portable radios being imported. When a $5 tariff is implemented, the new equilibrium is P=$15 and Q=3,500 radios per year, with $6,250 collected in tariff revenues, $6,250 transferred from consumer surplus to domestic producers, and a deadweight loss of $3,125. Under a voluntary export restraint, the prices, quantities, and deadweight losses are the same as in the tariff scenario. The main difference is the distribution of revenues, with export restraint revenues going to foreign suppliers instead of the domestic government.

Step by step solution

01

a. Finding the domestic equilibrium

To find the domestic equilibrium, set the demand and supply equations equal to each other, and solve for \(\mathrm{P}\) and \(\mathrm{Q}\): $$5,000 - 100P = 150P$$ Then, $$5,000 = 250P$$ $$P=20$$ Now use either the demand or supply equation to find the equilibrium quantity: $$Q = 5,000 - 100(20) = 5,000 - 2,000 = 3,000$$ The domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market is \(\mathrm{P} = \$20\) and \(\mathrm{Q} = 3,000\) radios per year.
02

b. Analyzing the impact of free trade on market equilibrium

If trade were unencumbered, portable radios would be imported at a world price of \(\$10\) per radio. In this case, the demand equation remains the same, but now quantity supplied decreases since \(\mathrm{P}\) decreases: $$Q^s = 150(10) = 1,500$$ To find the imported quantity of radios, we need to evaluate the domestic demand at this lower world price: $$Q^d = 5,000 - 100(10) = 5,000 - 1,000 = 4,000$$ The imported quantity is the difference between the domestic demand and the domestic supply: $$Q^I = Q^d - Q^s = 4,000 - 1,500 = 2,500$$ Therefore, with free trade, the new market equilibrium is \(\mathrm{P} = \$10\) and \(\mathrm{Q} = 4,000\) radios per year, with \(2,500\) portable radios being imported.
03

c. Analyzing the impact of a \(\$5\) tariff on the market equilibrium

If a \(\$5\) tariff is implemented, the new market price would increase to \(\$15\). Thus, the quantity supplied would increase and the domestic demand would decrease: $$Q^{s'} = 150 (15) = 2,250$$ $$Q^{d'} = 5,000 - 100(15) = 5,000 - 1,500 = 3,500$$ The imported quantity is the difference between the new domestic demand and the new domestic supply: $$Q^{I'} = Q^{d'} - Q^{s'} = 3,500 - 2,250 = 1,250$$ 1. Tariff revenues: The government would collect tariff revenues based on the tariff per radio and the quantity of radios imported: $$\$5 * 1,250 = \$6,250$$ 2. Change in consumer surplus: The increase in price from \(\$10\) to \(\$15\) redistributes consumer surplus to domestic producers. The transferred consumer surplus can be calculated as a result of the price increase multiplied by the decrease in imported quantity: $$(\$15 - \$10) * 1,250 = \$6,250$$ 3. The deadweight loss from the tariff can be calculated as the difference in imported quantities between the free trade and tariff scenarios, multiplied by the tariff: $$(\$5 * (2,500 - 1,250)) / 2 = \$3,125$$ The new equilibrium with the tariff is \(\mathrm{P}=\$15\) and \(\mathrm{Q}=3,500\) radios per year, with $$\$6,250$$ collected in tariff revenues, $$\$6,250$$ transferred from consumer surplus to domestic producers, and $$\$3,125$$ of deadweight loss.
04

d. Analyzing the effect of voluntary export limits on the market equilibrium

If the government reached an agreement with foreign suppliers to voluntarily limit their portable radio exports to \(1,250,000\) per year, the effect would be similar to that of a tariff, but with some crucial differences: 1. Price impact: With a voluntary export restraint, there will be a new effective world price equivalent to the domestic price that equates the quantity supplied by importing country producers with the voluntary restraint quantity. Let's denote this new price by \(\mathrm{P'}\). In this case, \(Q^{I'} = 1,250\). Assuming all other things being equal, this would have a price effect similar to the tariff. 2. Revenue impact: Unlike the case of a tariff, the revenue generated by the higher price under voluntary export restraints would accrue to the foreign suppliers rather than to the domestic government. So, there would be no tariff revenue collected by the government. 3. Deadweight loss: Since the quantity of imported radios is the same as in the tariff scenario, the deadweight loss would also be the same, at $$\$3,125$$. The main difference between the tariff and the voluntary export restraint is the distribution of the collected revenues: tariff revenues go to the domestic government, while revenues under voluntary export restraints go to foreign suppliers. The prices, quantities, and deadweight losses in both scenarios are the same.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The handmade snuffbox industry is composed of 100 identical firms, each having short-run total costs given by \\[ S T C=0.5 q^{2}+10 q+5 \\] and short-run marginal costs given by \\[ S M C=q+10 \\] where \(q\) is the output of snuffboxes per day. a. What is the short-run supply curve for each snuffbox maker? What is the short-run supply curve for the market as a whole? b. Suppose the demand for total snuffbox production is given by \\[ Q=1,100-50 P \\] What will be the equilibrium in this marketplace? What will each firm's total short-run profits be? c. Graph the market equilibrium and compute total short-run producer surplus in this case. d. Show that the total producer surplus you calculated in part (c) is equal to total industry profits plus industry short-run fixed costs. e. Suppose the government imposed a \(\$ 3\) tax on snuffboxes. How would this tax change the market equilibrium? f. How would the burden of this tax be shared between snuffbox buyers and sellers? g. Calculate the total loss of producer surplus as a result of the taxation of snuffboxes. Show that this loss equals the change in total short-run profits in the snuffbox industry. Why do fixed costs not enter into this computation of the change in short-run producer surplus?

Suppose that the demand for stilts is given by \\[ Q=1,500-50 P \\] and that the long-run total operating costs of each stilt-making firm in a competitive industry are given by \\[ C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q \\] Entrepreneurial talent for stilt making is scarce. The supply curve for entrepreneurs is given by \\[ Q_{S}=0.25 w \\] where \(w\) is the annual wage paid. Suppose also that each stilt-making firm requires one (and only one) entrepreneur (hence the quantity of entrepreneurs hired is equal to the number of firms). Long-run total costs for each firm are then given by \\[ C(q, w)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+w \\] a. What is the long-run equilibrium quantity of stilts produced? How many stilts are produced by each firm? What is the long-run equilibrium price of stilts? How many firms will there be? How many entrepreneurs will be hired, and what is their wage? b. Suppose that the demand for stilts shifts outward to \\[ Q=2,428-50 P \\] How would you now answer the questions posed in part (a)? c. Because stilt-making entrepreneurs are the cause of the upward-sloping long-run supply curve in this problem, they will receive all rents generated as industry output expands. Calculate the increase in rents between parts (a) and (b). Show that this value is identical to the change in long-run producer surplus as measured along the stilt supply curve.

demand is given by \\[ Q=1,500-50 P \\] a. What is the industry's long-run supply schedule? b. What is the long-run equilibrium price \(\left(P^{*}\right) ?\) The total industry output \(\left(Q^{*}\right) ?\) The output of each firm \(\left(q^{*}\right) ?\) The number of firms? The profits of each firm? c. The short-run total cost function associated with each firm's long-run equilibrium output is given by \\[ C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+200 \\] Calculate the short-run average and marginal cost function. At what output level does short-run average cost reach a minimum? d. Calculate the short-run supply function for each firm and the industry short-run supply function. e. Suppose now that the market demand function shifts upward to \(Q=2,000-50 P .\) Using this new demand curve, answer part (b) for the very short run when firms cannot change their outputs. f. In the short run, use the industry short-run supply function to recalculate the answers to (b). g. What is the new long-run equilibrium for the industry?

The perfectly competitive videotape-copying industry is composed of many firms that can copy five tapes per day at an average cost of \(\$ 10\) per tape. Each firm must also pay a royalty to film studios, and the per-film royalty rate \((r)\) is an increasing function of total industry output (Q): \\[ r=0.002 Q \\] Demand is given by \\[ Q=1,050-50 P \\] a. Assuming the industry is in long-run equilibrium, what will be the equilibrium price and quantity of copied tapes? How many tape firms will there be? What will the per-film royalty rate be? b. Suppose that demand for copied tapes increases to \\[ Q=1,600-50 P \\] In this case, what is the long-run equilibrium price and quantity for copied tapes? How many tape firms are there? What is the per-film royalty rate? c. Graph these long-run equilibria in the tape market, and calculate the increase in producer surplus between the situations described in parts (a) and (b). d. Show that the increase in producer surplus is precisely equal to the increase in royalties paid as \(Q\) expands incrementally from its level in part (b) to its level in part (c). e. Suppose that the government institutes a \(\$ 5.50\) per-film tax on the film-copying industry. Assuming that the demand for copied films is that given in part (a), how will this tax affect the market equilibrium? f. How will the burden of this tax be allocated between consumers and producers? What will be the loss of consumer and producer surplus? g. Show that the loss of producer surplus as a result of this tax is borne completely by the film studios. Explain your result intuitively.

The development of optimal tax policy has been a major topic in public finance for centuries. \(^{17}\) Probably the most famous result in the theory of optimal taxation is due to the English economist Frank Ramsey, who conceptualized the problem as how to structure a tax system that would collect a given amount of revenues with the minimal deadweight loss. \(^{18}\) Specifically, suppose there are \(n\) goods \(\left(x_{i} \text { with prices } p_{i}\right)\) to be taxed with a sequence of ad valorem taxes (see Problem 12.10 ) whose rates are given by \(t_{i}(i=1, n) .\) Therefore, total tax revenue is given by \(T=\sum_{i=1}^{n} t_{i} p_{i} x_{i} .\) Ramsey's problem is for a fixed \(T\) to choose tax rates that will minimize total deadweight loss \(D W=\sum_{i=1}^{n} D W\left(t_{i}\right)\) a. Use the Lagrange multiplier method to show that the solution to Ramsey's problem requires \(t_{i}=\lambda\left(1 / e_{s}-1 / e_{\mathrm{D}}\right),\) where \(\lambda\) is the Lagrange multiplier for the tax constraint. b. Interpret the Ramsey result intuitively. c. Describe some shortcomings of the Ramsey approach to optimal taxation.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free