Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

How would you expect an increase in output price, \(P\), to affect the demand for capital and labor inputs? a. Explain graphically why, if neither input is inferior, it seems clear that a rise in \(P\) must not reduce the demand for either factor. b. Show that the graphical presumption from part (a) is demonstrated by the input demand functions that can be derived in the Cobb-Douglas case. c. Use the profit function to show how the presence of inferior inputs would lead to ambiguity in the effect of \(P\) on input demand.

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: In the presence of inferior inputs, the effect of an increase in output price on the demand for capital and labor inputs is ambiguous, as the relationship between output and input demand is no longer straightforward. An increase in output price might increase or decrease the demand for a particular input, depending on whether it is inferior or not.

Step by step solution

01

Part (a): Graphical Explanation #

Let's assume that a firm produces output using two inputs: capital (K) and labor (L). The production function can be represented by the isoquant curve. Isoquants represent combinations of inputs that produce the same level of output. When the output price, \(P\), increases, the firm seeks to maximize profits by producing more output. To explain graphically, we can draw an isoquant map showing isoquants for different levels of output. However, since higher isoquants represent higher outputs, as the output price increases and firms seek to produce more, they will move to a higher isoquant. If neither input is inferior, which means that as output increases, the firm will need to use more of both K and L, the firm will move towards a higher isoquant that requires more capital and labor. Consequently, a rise in \(P\) must not reduce the demand for either factor.
02

Part (b): Cobb-Douglas Input Demand Functions #

Suppose the firm produces output according to the Cobb-Douglas production function: \[F(K,L) = A K^\alpha L^\beta\] where A, \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\) are constant parameters. In the Cobb-Douglas case, the input demand functions for capital and labor are given by: \[K^* = \alpha \frac{w}{r}L^*\] \[L^* = \beta \frac{r}{w}K^*\] where \(K^*\) and \(L^*\) are the optimal demand for capital and labor, and w and r represent the cost of labor and capital, respectively. Notice that both \(K^*\) and \(L^*\) are increasing functions with respect to P. Thus, the graphical presumption from part (a) is demonstrated by the input demand functions in the Cobb-Douglas case.
03

Part (c): Profit Function and Inferior Inputs #

Let's assume the profit function is given by: \[\pi = PF(K,L) - wL - rK\] where \(\pi\) represents profit, P is the output price, F(K,L) is the production function, w and r are the costs of labor and capital as before. Taking partial derivatives of the profit function with respect to K and L, we get the following conditions for profit maximization: \[\frac{\partial \pi}{\partial K} = P\frac{\partial F(K,L)}{\partial K} - r = 0\] \[\frac{\partial \pi}{\partial L} = P\frac{\partial F(K,L)}{\partial L} - w = 0\] When neither input is inferior, an increase in P leads to an increase in output, which in turn increases the demand for both K and L. However, if one of the inputs is inferior, an increase in output may reduce the demand for that particular input. In that case, we may observe that \(\frac{\partial F(K,L)}{\partial K}\) or \(\frac{\partial F(K,L)}{\partial L}\) is negative. The presence of inferior inputs creates ambiguity in the effect of \(P\) on input demand because the relationship between output and input demand is no longer straightforward. An increase in \(P\) might increase or decrease the demand for a particular input, depending on whether it is inferior or not. Thus, in the presence of inferior inputs, conclusions drawn from graphical analysis in part (a) and Cobb-Douglas input-demand functions in part (b) may not hold.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

With a CES production function of the form \(q=\left(k^{\rho}+l^{\rho}\right)^{\gamma / \rho}\) a whole lot of algebra is needed to compute the profit function as \(\Pi(P, v, w)=K P^{1 /(1-\gamma)}\left(v^{1-\alpha}+w^{1-\sigma}\right)^{\gamma /(1-\sigma)(\gamma-1)},\) where \(\sigma=1 /(1-\rho)\) and \(K\) is a constant a. If you are a glutton for punishment (or if your instructor is), prove that the profit function takes this form. Perhaps the easiest way to do so is to start from the CES cost function in Example 10.2 b. Explain why this profit function provides a reasonable representation of a firm's behavior only for \(0<\gamma<1\) c. Explain the role of the elasticity of substitution ( \(\sigma\) ) in this profit function. What is the supply function in this case? How does \(\sigma\) determine the extent to which that function shifts when input prices change? e. Derive the input demand functions in this case. How are these functions affected by the size of \(\sigma ?\)

John's Lawn Mowing Service is a small business that acts as a price-taker (i.e., \(M R=P\) ). The prevailing market price of lawn mowing is \(\$ 20\) per acre. John's costs are given by total cost \(=0.1 q^{2}+10 q+50\) where \(q=\) the number of acres John chooses to cut a day. a. How many acres should John choose to cut to maximize profit? b. Calculate John's maximum daily profit. c. Graph these results, and label John's supply curve.

This problem concerns the relationship between demand and marginal revenue curves for a few functional forms. a. Show that, for a linear demand curve, the marginal revenue curve bisects the distance between the vertical axis and the demand curve for any price. b. Show that, for any linear demand curve, the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves is \(-1 / b \cdot q\) where \(b(<0)\) is the slope of the demand curve. c. Show that, for a constant elasticity demand curve of the form \(q=a P^{b}\), the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves is a constant ratio of the height of the demand curve, with this constant depending on the price elasticity of demand. d. Show that, for any downward-sloping demand curve, the vertical distance between the demand and marginal revenue curves at any point can be found by using a linear approximation to the demand curve at that point and applying the procedure described in part (b). e. Graph the results of parts (a)-(d) of this problem.

The production function for a firm in the business of calculator assembly is given by \\[ q=2 \sqrt{l} \\] where \(q\) denotes finished calculator output and \(l\) denotes hours of labor input. The firm is a price-taker both for calculators (which sell for \(P\) ) and for workers (which can be hired at a wage rate of \(w\) per hour). a. What is the total cost function for this firm? b. What is the profit function for this firm? c. What is the supply function for assembled calculators \([q(P, w)] ?\) d. What is this firm's demand for labor function \([l(P, w)] ?\) e. Describe intuitively why these functions have the form they do.

The market for high-quality caviar is dependent on the weather. If the weather is good, there are many fancy parties and caviar sells for \(\$ 30\) per pound. In bad weather it sells for only \(\$ 20\) per pound. Caviar produced one weck will not keep until the next week. A small caviar producer has a cost function given by $$C=0.5 q^{2}+5 q+100$$ where \(q\) is weekly caviar production. Production decisions must be made before the weather (and the price of caviar) is known, but it is known that good weather and bad weather each occur with a probability of 0.5 a. How much caviar should this firm produce if it wishes to maximize the expected value of its profits? b. Suppose the owner of this firm has a utility function of the form \\[ \text { utility }=\sqrt{\pi} \\] where \(\pi\) is weekly profits. What is the expected utility associated with the output strategy defined in part (a)? c. Can this firm owner obtain a higher utility of profits by producing some output other than that specified in parts (a) and (b)? Explain. d. Suppose this firm could predict next week's price but could not influence that price. What strategy would maximize expected profits in this case? What would expected profits be?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free