Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The domestic demand for portable radios is given by \\[Q=5,000-100 P,\\] where price \((P)\) is measured in dollars and quantity \((Q)\) is measured in thousands of radios per year. The domestic supply curve for radios is given by $$Q=150 P.$$ a. What is the domestic equilibrium in the portable radio market? b. Suppose portable radios can be imported at a world price of $$\$ 10$$ per radio. If trade were unencumbered, what would the new market equilibrium be? How many portable radios would be imported? c. If domestic portable radio producers succeeded in having a $$\$ 5$$ tariff implemented, how would this change the market equilibrium? How much would be collected in tariff revenues? How much consumer surplus would be transferred to domestic producers? What would the deadweight loss from the tariff be? d. How would your results from part (c) be changed if the government reached an agreement with foreign suppliers to "voluntarily" limit the portable radios they export to \(1,250,000\) per year? Explain how this differs from the case of a tariff.

Short Answer

Expert verified
The domestic equilibrium is at \(P = \$20\) and \(Q = 3,000,000\). With a \$10 world price, \(2,500\) radios are imported. A \$5 tariff results in \(1,250\) imports and \$6,250,000 in tariff revenue. A voluntary export limit affects surplus differently than a tariff.

Step by step solution

01

Find the Domestic Equilibrium

To find the domestic equilibrium, set the demand equation equal to the supply equation. \[\begin{align*} 5,000 - 100P &= 150P. \end{align*}\] Solving for \(P\), combine like terms: \[\begin{align*} 5,000 &= 250P. \end{align*}\] Divide both sides by 250: \[\begin{align*} P &= 20. \end{align*}\] Substitute \(P = 20\) back into either the supply or demand equation to find \(Q\): \[\begin{align*} Q &= 150 \times 20 = 3,000. \end{align*}\] Thus, the domestic equilibrium price is \(\$20\) per radio and the quantity is \(3,000,000\) radios.
02

New Market Equilibrium with World Price

With a world price of \$10, substitute \(P = 10\) into the demand equation: \[\begin{align*} Q_d = 5,000 - 100 \times 10 = 4,000. \end{align*}\] Now, substitute \(P = 10\) in the supply equation: \[\begin{align*} Q_s = 150 \times 10 = 1,500. \end{align*}\] At this world price, 4,000 radios are demanded domestically, and 1,500 radios are supplied domestically. Thus, \(4,000 - 1,500 = 2,500\) radios must be imported.
03

Effect of a $5 Tariff

With the \\(5 tariff, the domestic price increases to \\)15. Substitute \(P = 15\) into the demand equation: \[\begin{align*} Q_d = 5,000 - 100 \times 15 = 3,500. \end{align*}\] Substitute \(P = 15\) into the supply equation: \[\begin{align*} Q_s = 150 \times 15 = 2,250. \end{align*}\] Imports are now \(3,500 - 2,250 = 1,250\) radios. The tariff revenue is \(1,250 \times 5 = 6,250,000\) dollars. The consumer surplus transfer to domestic producers is calculated using changes in prices and quantities.
04

Calculate Tariff Effects

Next, calculate consumer surplus transfer and deadweight loss. The increase in domestic price from \\(10 to \\)15 results in a reduced consumer surplus, partially transferred to producers. Deadweight loss results from the reduction in quantity traded. The calculation involves changes in surplus areas and quantities, which typically requires diagrammatic analysis or additional data on consumer-producer elasticity.
05

Voluntary Export Restraint

If exports are voluntarily limited to 1,250,000 radios, the effect differs from a tariff since consumer surplus loss from price changes goes entirely abroad, while domestic surplus from reduced import volume is limited by the voluntary agreement. The domestic price might not adjust exactly like in a tariff scenario.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Demand and Supply Equations
In a market, demand and supply equations are fundamental in determining the equilibrium price and quantity of goods. The demand equation is derived from consumer preferences and purchasing power. It shows how many goods consumers are willing to buy at different prices. In our example, the demand equation is \(Q_d = 5,000 - 100P\). As we can see, as the price \(P\) increases, the quantity demanded \(Q_d\) decreases, which is typical of most goods.
On the other hand, the supply equation originates from the producers' perspective. It indicates how much of a good producers are willing to sell at varying prices. The supply equation in this example is \(Q_s = 150P\). Here, as the price \(P\) rises, the quantity supplied \(Q_s\) also rises because higher prices make production more profitable for suppliers.
Finding the equilibrium involves setting the demand equation equal to the supply equation. This provides the point where the quantity consumers want to buy equals the quantity producers want to sell, resulting in no excess supply or demand. In this example, solving \(5,000 - 100P = 150P\) yields an equilibrium price of \( \$20 \) and a quantity of 3,000,000 radios. This ensures a balanced market where the quantities are equal at a specific price.
Tariffs and Trade Policies
Tariffs are taxes imposed on imports to protect domestic industries from foreign competition. By making imported goods more expensive, tariffs aim to encourage consumers to buy domestically produced goods.
When a tariff is implemented, it increases the market price of the imported goods. For example, in our exercise, a \( \\(5 \) tariff increases the price of imported radios from \( \\)10 \) to \( \$15 \). This encourages domestic production by raising the price consumers pay, thus boosting domestic supply.
Trade policies like voluntary export restraints (VERs) are another way to influence trade. A VER is an agreement between exporting and importing countries where the exporter agrees to limit the quantity of goods sent to the importing country. Unlike tariffs, VERs do not generate revenue for the domestic government but still reduce competition for domestic producers by limiting foreign supply. However, the price effect on the domestic market may not be as predictable as with a straightforward tariff.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer surplus is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good versus what they actually pay. It represents the benefit consumers get from purchasing goods at market prices lower than their maximum willingness to pay. In a market equilibrium without tariffs, consumer surplus is maximized because imports lower prices.
Producer surplus, on the other hand, is the difference between what producers receive for a good versus their minimum acceptable price. It reflects the additional benefit producers receive from selling at the market price above their cost.
  • With tariffs, consumer surplus decreases because consumers pay higher prices for the same quantity.
  • Producer surplus increases because domestic producers sell more at the higher tariff-inclusive price.
  • Tariff revenue is collected by the government, representing a financial gain.
  • However, there is a deadweight loss, which is the loss of economic efficiency due to the decrease in the quantity traded.
In the exercise, a \( \$5 \) tariff causes a partial consumer surplus transfer to domestic producers, but it also results in a net deadweight loss. This efficiency loss represents the transactions that no longer happen due to the price increase, which would have occurred without the tariff.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose there are 1,000 identical firms producing diamonds. Let the total cost function for each firm be given by \\[C(q, w)=q^{2}+w q;\\] where \(q\) is the firm's output level and \(w\) is the wage rate of diamond cutters. a. If \(w=10,\) what will be the firm's (short-run) supply curve? What is the industry's supply curve? How many diamonds will be produced at a price of 20 cach? How many more diamonds would be produced at a price of 21 ? b. Suppose the wages of diamond cutters depend on the total quantity of diamonds produced and suppose the form of this relationship is given by \\[w=0.002 Q;\\] here \(Q\) represents total industry output, which is 1,000 times the output of the typical firm. In this situation, show that the firm's marginal cost (and short-run supply) curve depends on \(Q .\) What is the industry supply curve? How much will be produced at a price of 20 ? How much more will be produced at a price of 21 ? What do you conclude about the shape of the short-run supply curve?

A perfcctly competitive industry has a large number of potential entrants. Each firm has an identical cost structure such that long-run average cost is minimized at an output of 20 units \(\left(q_{i}=20\right) .\) The minimum average cost is \(\$ 10\) per unit. Total market demand is given by \\[Q=1,500-50 P.\\] a. What is the industry's long-run supply schedule? b. What is the long-run equilibrium price \(\left(P^{*}\right)\) ? The total industry output \(\left(Q^{*}\right)\) ? The output of each firm \(\left(q^{*}\right)\) ? The number of firms? The profits of each firm? c. The short-run total cost function associated with each firm's long-run equilibrium output is given by \\[C(q)=0.5 q^{2}-10 q+200.\\] Calculate the short-run average and marginal cost function. At what output level does shortrun average cost reach a minimum? d. Calculate the short-run supply function for each firm and the industry short-run supply function. c. Suppose now that the market demand function shifts upward to \(Q=2,000-50 P\). Using this new demand curve, answer part (b) for the very short run when firms cannot change their outputs. f. In the short run, use the industry short-run supply function to recalculate the answers to (b). g. What is the new long-run equilibrium for the industry?

Suppose there are 100 identical firms in a perfectly competitive industry. Each firm has a short-run total cost function of the form \\[C(q)=\frac{1}{300} q^{3}+0.2 q^{2}+4 q+10.\\] a. Calculate the firm's short-run supply curve with \(q\) as a function of market price \((P)\). b. On the assumption that there are no interaction effects among costs of the firms in the industry, calculate the short-run industry supply curve. c. Suppose market demand is given by \(Q=-200 P+8,000 .\) What will be the short-run equilibrium price-quantity combination?

The perfectly competitive videotape copying industry is composed of many firms that can copy five tapes per day at an average cost of \(\$ 10\) per tape. Each firm must also pay a royalty to film studios, and the perfilm royalty rate \((r)\) is an increasing function of total industry output \((Q):\) \\[r=0.002 Q.\\] \\[Q=1,050-50 P.\\] a. Assuming the industry is in long-run equilibrium, what will be the equilibrium price and quantity of copied tapes? How many tape firms will there be? What will the per-film royalty rate be? b. Suppose that demand for copied tapes increases to \\[Q=1,600-50 P.\\] In this case, what is the long-run equilibrium price and quantity for copied tapes? How many tape firms are there? What is the per-film royalty rate? c. Graph these long-run equilibria in the tape market and calculate the increase in producer surplus between the situations described in parts (a) and (b). d. Show that the increase in producer surplus is precisely equal to the increase in royalties paid as \(Q\) expands incrementally from its level in part (b) to its level in part (c). e. Suppose that the government institutes a \(\$ 5.50\) per-film tax on the film copying industry. Assuming that the demand for copied films is that given in part (a), how will this tax affect the market equilibrium? f. How will the burden of this tax be allocated between consumers and producers? What will be the loss of consumer and producer surplus? g. Show that the loss of producer surplus as a result of this tax is borne completely by the film studios. Explain your result intuitively.

A perfectly competitive market has 1,000 firms. In the very short run, cach of the firms has a fixed supply of 100 units. The market demand is given by \\[Q=160,000-10,000 P.\\] a. Calculate the equilibrium price in the very short run. b. Calculate the demand schedule facing any one firm in this industry. c. Calculate what the equilibrium price would be if one of the sellers decided to sell nothing or if one seller decided to sell 200 units. d. At the original equilibrium point, calculate the elasticity of the industry demand curve and the elasticity of the demand curve facing any one seller. Suppose now that, in the short run, each firm has a supply curve that shows the quantity the firm will supply \(\left(q_{i}\right)\) as a function of market price. The specific form of this supply curve is given by \\[q_{i}=-200+50 P.\\] Using this short-run supply response, supply revised answers to (a)-(d).

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free