Chapter 20: Problem 5
The efficiency loss of imposing an excise tax is due to: a. Paying a higher price per unit. b. Producing and consuming fewer units.
Short Answer
Expert verified
The efficiency loss is due to producing and consuming fewer units.
Step by step solution
01
Understanding the Effect of Excise Tax
An excise tax is imposed on a good or service, leading to a higher price paid by consumers and potentially lower quantity produced or consumed. It's essential to understand how this tax impacts the market equilibrium, specifically regarding changes in quantity consumed and produced.
02
Analyzing Price Impact
When an excise tax is imposed, the supplier's production costs effectively increase, leading to higher prices for consumers. This is reflected as consumers invariably end up paying a portion of the tax, often leading to a reduced incentive to purchase the good.
03
Impact on Quantity
The imposition of an excise tax usually results in higher prices, which can deter consumption. As a result, fewer units of the good are sold and produced. This reduction in quantity transacted represents a loss of efficiency in the market.
04
Conclusion on Efficiency Loss
The efficiency loss mainly arises from the reduction in quantity produced and consumed. The market fails to achieve equilibrium where consumer and producer surplus is maximized, resulting in what is known as a 'deadweight loss.'
Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!
-
Full Textbook Solutions
Get detailed explanations and key concepts
-
Unlimited Al creation
Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...
-
Ads-free access
To over 500 millions flashcards
-
Money-back guarantee
We refund you if you fail your exam.
Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!
Key Concepts
These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.
Excise Tax
An excise tax is a specific type of tax imposed directly on certain goods or services, such as tobacco, alcohol, or gasoline. When a government levies an excise tax, it directly affects the price set for that good or service. The primary aim is usually to decrease consumption of a potentially harmful product or to generate additional revenue.
The imposition of an excise tax increases the overall cost of production for suppliers. As suppliers adjust their pricing to cover the cost of the tax, consumers end up paying higher prices. This increase is not just a straightforward increment in cost but also leads to changes in consumer behavior. As prices rise, consumers may reduce their consumption of the taxed good, which can have a ripple effect on the market.
It’s important to note that how this tax is distributed between consumers and producers depends largely on the elasticity of demand and supply. In simple terms, elasticity measures how much the quantity demanded or supplied changes when there is a price change. If demand is inelastic, consumers will bear a larger share of the tax burden because their consumption doesn't change much with price increases.
The imposition of an excise tax increases the overall cost of production for suppliers. As suppliers adjust their pricing to cover the cost of the tax, consumers end up paying higher prices. This increase is not just a straightforward increment in cost but also leads to changes in consumer behavior. As prices rise, consumers may reduce their consumption of the taxed good, which can have a ripple effect on the market.
It’s important to note that how this tax is distributed between consumers and producers depends largely on the elasticity of demand and supply. In simple terms, elasticity measures how much the quantity demanded or supplied changes when there is a price change. If demand is inelastic, consumers will bear a larger share of the tax burden because their consumption doesn't change much with price increases.
Market Equilibrium
The point at which the quantity of a good demanded by consumers equals the quantity supplied by producers is known as market equilibrium. At this juncture, there is no excess supply or shortage, and the market efficiently allocates resources.
When an excise tax is imposed, it disrupts this delicate balance. By increasing the price of a good, the tax effectively shifts the supply curve, as suppliers need to account for the additional cost in their pricing. This leads to a new equilibrium where the quantity demanded decreases due to higher consumer prices, while the quantity supplied may also reduce.
As a result, the market finds a new balance point, but this typically occurs at a lower quantity and possibly a higher price than before the excise tax. This shift away from the original equilibrium can reduce total market transactions and thus impact overall economic efficiency.
When an excise tax is imposed, it disrupts this delicate balance. By increasing the price of a good, the tax effectively shifts the supply curve, as suppliers need to account for the additional cost in their pricing. This leads to a new equilibrium where the quantity demanded decreases due to higher consumer prices, while the quantity supplied may also reduce.
As a result, the market finds a new balance point, but this typically occurs at a lower quantity and possibly a higher price than before the excise tax. This shift away from the original equilibrium can reduce total market transactions and thus impact overall economic efficiency.
Deadweight Loss
Deadweight loss occurs when there is a decrease in total welfare, or economic efficiency, due to market interventions like taxes or subsidies. In the context of an excise tax, deadweight loss represents the lost transactions that would have occurred in an untaxed, free market.
To visualize deadweight loss, imagine a triangle on a supply and demand graph. The base of the triangle is the quantity reduction due to the tax, while the height represents the price increase. The area of this triangle represents the total economic transactions that are forgone due to the excise tax.
Essentially, deadweight loss is an economic side effect that indicates neither the producer nor the consumer benefits from the taxed transactions that didn’t happen. This inefficiency means less overall satisfaction in the economy, as fewer goods are traded and potentially beneficial exchanges are lost. Understanding deadweight loss is crucial as it highlights the cost associated with taxing policies and their impact on market dynamics.
To visualize deadweight loss, imagine a triangle on a supply and demand graph. The base of the triangle is the quantity reduction due to the tax, while the height represents the price increase. The area of this triangle represents the total economic transactions that are forgone due to the excise tax.
Essentially, deadweight loss is an economic side effect that indicates neither the producer nor the consumer benefits from the taxed transactions that didn’t happen. This inefficiency means less overall satisfaction in the economy, as fewer goods are traded and potentially beneficial exchanges are lost. Understanding deadweight loss is crucial as it highlights the cost associated with taxing policies and their impact on market dynamics.
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer and producer surplus are key concepts in understanding the benefits that buyers and sellers respectively gain from participating in a market.
**Consumer Surplus:** This is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good versus what they actually pay. It's a measure of the benefit consumers receive when they pay less than they were willing to.
**Producer Surplus:** Similar to consumer surplus, producer surplus quantifies the benefit to sellers. It’s the difference between the price at which producers are willing to sell a good, and the actual price they receive.
When an excise tax is implemented, both consumer and producer surplus are likely to decrease. The tax increases prices, reducing consumer purchases, hence diminishing their surplus. On the other hand, producers receive less for their products after paying the tax, reducing their surplus as well.
The reduction in these surpluses, coupled with the deadweight loss, highlights the inefficiency introduced by the tax. Evaluating these changes can provide insights into the broader economic impacts, helping policymakers weigh the benefits against the costs of an excise tax.
**Consumer Surplus:** This is the difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good versus what they actually pay. It's a measure of the benefit consumers receive when they pay less than they were willing to.
**Producer Surplus:** Similar to consumer surplus, producer surplus quantifies the benefit to sellers. It’s the difference between the price at which producers are willing to sell a good, and the actual price they receive.
When an excise tax is implemented, both consumer and producer surplus are likely to decrease. The tax increases prices, reducing consumer purchases, hence diminishing their surplus. On the other hand, producers receive less for their products after paying the tax, reducing their surplus as well.
The reduction in these surpluses, coupled with the deadweight loss, highlights the inefficiency introduced by the tax. Evaluating these changes can provide insights into the broader economic impacts, helping policymakers weigh the benefits against the costs of an excise tax.