Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

The socially optimal price \((P=M C)\) is socially optimal because: \(L O 12.7\) a. It reduces the monopolist's profit. b. It yields a normal profit. c. It minimizes ATC. d. It achieves allocative efficiency.

Short Answer

Expert verified
The correct answer is d: It achieves allocative efficiency.

Step by step solution

01

Understanding Socially Optimal Pricing

Socially optimal pricing is where the price of a good or service (P) is equal to the marginal cost (MC). This price leads to the optimal allocation of resources because it matches the cost of production with the value consumers place on the last unit consumed.
02

Analyze the Options

Review each given option to determine which aligns with the characteristics of socially optimal pricing. We especially want to identify the one that matches the definition of allocative efficiency.
03

Compare P=MC and Allocative Efficiency

Allocative efficiency occurs when resources are distributed in such a way that they produce the goods and services most desired by society. This happens when P=MC because the price consumers are willing to pay (P) reflects the additional cost of producing one more unit (MC), indicating no overproduction or underproduction.
04

Selecting the Correct Answer

Based on the characteristics of socially optimal pricing, we determine that it achieves allocative efficiency because the market is producing the quantity of goods that consumers most desire at that price.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Socially Optimal Pricing
Socially optimal pricing occurs when the price of a product or service is set equal to its marginal cost, meaning the price per unit is exactly what it costs to produce that additional unit. This pricing strategy is vital as it aligns perfectly with resource distribution preferences in society. By setting the price equal to the marginal cost, it ensures that resources are used efficiently, reflecting consumer willingness to pay exactly what it costs to produce the last unit. As such, this approach leads to a state in which the welfare surplus is maximized for society.

In practical terms, the socially optimal price minimizes deadweight loss—a loss of economic efficiency that occurs when equilibrium for the good or service is not achieved or is not achievable. By equating price and marginal cost, both producers and consumers benefit from exact value equivalence, ensuring that every unit produced fulfills a consumer need without wasting resources.
Marginal Cost Pricing
Marginal cost pricing is a method where the price set for each product equals the additional cost of producing that extra unit. It guides firms to focus on covering the cost of production effectively for each incremental unit. This pricing mechanism is instrumental in achieving allocative efficiency because it signals producers to adjust their output to the level where consumer demand meets the cost of production.

Key benefits of marginal cost pricing include:
  • Encouraging efficient resource use by avoiding overproduction or underproduction.
  • Ensuring that prices reflect the actual cost of goods produced, which can lead to more informed and better decision-making by firms.
  • Providing a straightforward framework for pricing decisions that align with societal welfare goals.
This approach is particularly advocated in public goods and services, where the aim is to serve the public interest over profit maximization. However, it might also result in challenges for firms as prices equal to marginal costs could be lower than average costs, leading to potential financial losses.
Resource Allocation
Resource allocation refers to the process of distributing available resources among various uses to maximize efficiency and meet the desired objectives. In economics, achieving optimal resource allocation is central to maximizing societal welfare. Markets guided by socially optimal pricing lead to resource allocation that reflects consumer preferences and production costs accurately.

When prices truly represent the marginal cost of production, resources are allocated in a way that each good or service is produced up to the point where the cost of the last unit equals the value to consumers. This ensures no resources are left unused or misallocated, supporting the idea of complete market efficiency where needs and wants are met without surplus or shortage.
  • Equitable: Aligns with consumer preferences and willingness to pay.
  • Efficient: Minimizes wastage and inefficiency in production and distribution.
  • Adaptable: Enables markets to adjust quickly to changing demands and supply circumstances.
Thus, effective resource allocation through mechanisms like P=MC pricing is essential for economic systems striving for efficiency and societal welfare.
Economics Education
Economics education plays a pivotal role in developing a thorough understanding of pricing and resource allocation strategies such as socially optimal pricing and marginal cost pricing. Understanding these concepts is crucial for anyone looking to grasp how markets operate efficiently and effectively.

The study of economics offers insights into:
  • The importance of pricing strategies in achieving allocative efficiency.
  • How to make informed decisions grounded in economic principles such as marginal costs and benefits.
  • Exploring the balance between consumer desires and resource capabilities to achieve optimal welfare states.
By integrating these concepts into education, learners can better appreciate the complexities of economic systems, equipping them with the tools needed to analyze market dynamics and make decisions that enhance economic well-being. It emphasizes the use of economic theories and models to solve real-world problems, fostering a generation that can critically assess and contribute to discussions on resource management and sustainable economic growth.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The main problem with imposing the socially optimal price \((P=\mathrm{MC})\) on a monopoly is that the socially optimal price: \(L O 12.7.\) a. May be so low that the regulated monopoly can't break even. b. May cause the regulated monopoly to engage in price discrimination. c. May be higher than the monopoly price.

Suppose that a monopolist can segregate his buyers into two different groups to which he can charge two different prices. In order to maximize profit, the monopolist should charge a higher price to the group that has: \(L O 12.6.\) a. The higher elasticity of demand. b. The lower elasticity of demand. c. Richer members.

The MR curve of a perfectly competitive firm is horizontal. The MR curve of a monopoly firm is: \(L O 12.3\) a. Horizontal, too. c. Downsloping. b. Upsloping. d. It depends.

How often do perfectly competitive firms engage in price discrimination? LO12.6 a. Never. b. Rarely. c. Often. d. Always.

Use the following demand schedule to calculate total revenue and marginal revenue at each quantity. Plot the demand, totalrevenue, and marginal-revenue curves, and explain the relationships between them. Explain why the marginal revenue of the fourth unit of output is \(\$ 3.50,\) even though its price is \(\$ 5 .\) Use Chapter 6 's total-revenue test for price elasticity to designate the elastic and inelastic segments of your graphed demand curve. What generalization can you make as to the relationship between marginal revenue and elasticity of demand? Suppose the marginal cost of successive units of output was zero. What output would the profit-seeking firm produce? Finally, use your analysis to explain why a monopolist would never produce in the inelastic region of demand. LO12.3 $$\begin{array}{|c|c|c|c|} \hline \text { Price (P) } & \begin{array}{c} \text { Quantity } \\ \text { Demanded (Q) } \end{array} & \text { Price (P) } & \begin{array}{c} \text { Quantity } \\ \text { Demanded (O) } \end{array} \\ \hline \$ 7.00 & 0 & \$ 4.50 & 5 \\ 6.50 & 1 & 4.00 & 6 \\ 6.00 & 2 & 3.50 & 7 \\ 5.50 & 3 & 3.00 & 8 \\ 5.00 & 4 & 2.50 & 9 \\ \hline \end{array}$$

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free