Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

What is the difference between the voting paradox and the Arrow impossibility theorem?

Short Answer

Expert verified
The Voting Paradox and Arrow's Impossibility Theorem both deal with issues in collective decision-making. However, the Voting Paradox refers to a specific situation where majority preference is cyclic and inconsistent, while Arrow's Impossibility Theorem is a broader assertion that no ideal voting system can exist that transforms individual rankings into a collective ranking without violating some principles of fairness or rationality.

Step by step solution

01

Understanding the Voting Paradox

The Voting Paradox, also known as the Condorcet Paradox, is a situation in social choice theory where collective preferences can be cyclic, even if the preferences of individual voters are not. This means that majority preferences can be intransitive, even though the preferences of individual voters are transitive. In other words, society might prefer choice A over B, B over C but, paradoxically, prefer C over A.
02

Understanding Arrow's Impossibility Theorem

Arrow's Impossibility Theorem, proposed by Kenneth Arrow, indicates that when voters have three or more distinct alternatives (options), no rank-order electoral system can convert the ranked preferences of individuals into a community-wide (complete and transitive) ranking while also meeting a certain set of criteria outlined by Arrow. These criteria are Non-Dictatorship, Pareto efficiency, and Independence of irrelevant alternatives.
03

Comparing the Voting Paradox and Arrow's Impossibility Theorem

The Voting Paradox and Arrow's Impossibility Theorem, though related, are different in their scope and implications. The Voting Paradox illustrates a specific situation where the majority rule may fail to produce consistent results, while Arrow’s Theorem is a general proof demonstrating that no voting system can accurately reflect individual preferences into a collective decision without violating some principles of fairness or rationality.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Condorcet Paradox
The Condorcet Paradox, also recognized within the realm of social choice theory, surfaces when collective preferences among three or more options become cyclical and incoherent—even when individual voter preferences are orderly and transitive. To illustrate, in a group of voters where each has a clear preference ranking of A over B, B over C, and C over A, the group decision becomes inconsistent. This paradox underlines a fundamental challenge in designing social decision-making processes: the majority rule does not always yield a rational outcome for society as a whole. This realization helps us understand why constructing a fair and logical voting system is more complex than it might initially seem.
Social Choice Theory
Social choice theory explores the methods and implications of aggregating individual preferences, judgments, and welfare to reach a collective decision or social welfare. It intersects economics, political science, and philosophy, examining how we can reconcile individual opinions to reach a decision that represents the group. Social choice theory involves devising rules and systems that reflect the society's overall wants and needs from the diverse individual preferences. It confronts numerous challenges, including the Condorcet Paradox and Arrow’s Theorem, which highlight the difficulties in creating a flawless system that translates individual preferences into a coherent group choice.
Rank-Order Electoral Systems
Rank-order electoral systems, also known as preference voting systems, enable voters to list candidates or options in order of preference. These systems aim to provide a more nuanced method for voters to express their choices. They are used to derive a winner based on the rankings, with various methods like instant-runoff voting, single transferable vote, and Borda count. Despite their attempt to accurately reflect voter preferences, Kenneth Arrow's theorem suggests the impossibility of creating a perfect rank-order voting system that adheres to certain fairness criteria.
Non-Dictatorship
The criterion of Non-Dictatorship is pivotal to Arrow's Impossibility Theorem. It mandates that no single voter possesses the authority to always determine the group's preference, regardless of the other voters' wishes. It is a critical component of a democratic voting system, ensuring that the collective decision reflects the group's opinion rather than being imposed by a single individual. This principle is a bulwark against autocratic rule within a voting system, reinforcing the concept that the final outcome must be the product of fair and equal consideration of all members' preferences.
Pareto Efficiency
In the context of social choice and voting systems, Pareto efficiency is a scenario where no individual's situation can be improved without worsening another's. Arrow's theorem incorporates this concept, suggesting that a collective decision-making rule should satisfy Pareto efficiency, in the sense that if every individual prefers one option over another, the group's ranking should reflect the same preference. It's a principle of unanimity; if everyone agrees that option A is better than option B, the social choice should naturally be A over B. This criterion emphasizes the minimal standard for a group's decision to be considered rational and socially beneficial.
Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives
The principle of Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) states that the social preference between two options should not be affected by the introduction or removal of a third, unrelated option. In simpler terms, if choice A is preferred over choice B, introducing a choice C should not change this preference, unless C becomes the most preferred option. This criterion, outlined as part of Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem, insists on consistent preferences in the presence of additional choices. It asserts that the integrity of voters' preferences between any two options should not be distorted by the addition of non-preferred alternatives. Arrow's theorem shows that no rank-order voting system can guarantee this independence, alongside meeting other fairness criteria.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

An article in a Federal Reserve publication noted that "nearly all taxes create some market inefficiency in the form of deadweight loss." The article further noted that when something is taxed, the result is "an outcome in which both [buyers and sellers] would gain from more production." a. Briefly explain why taxes result in deadweight loss. b. If buyers and sellers would gain from more production of a good or service that is taxed, why doesn't more of the good or service get produced?"

(Related to the Chapter Opener on page 600 ) In 2017 , the Trump administration proposed changes to the federal tax code, including reducing the top corporate income tax rate from 35 percent to 15 percent. An article in the Wall Street Journal noted, "A tax overhaul could give companies more incentive to invest." a. What type of investments is the article referring to? Why would cutting the corporate income tax rate lead companies to engage in more investment? b. Some policymakers and economists are critical of cuts in the corporate income tax rate because they argue that such cuts increase income inequality. Does the incidence of the corporate income tax matter in evaluating this argument? Briefly explain.

What does tax incidence mean?

(Related to Solved Problem 18.4 on page 621 ) Evaluate the following statement: "Policies to redistribute income are desperately needed in the United States. Without such policies, the roughly 13 percent of the population that is currently poor has no hope of ever climbing above the poverty line."

Suppose the government eliminates the federal income \(\operatorname{tax}\) and replaces it with a consumption tax. With a consumption tax, individuals pay a tax on only the part of their income they spend rather than save. Think about the effect of this change on the market for automobiles. Can you necessarily tell what will happen to the price and quantity of automobiles? Briefly explain.

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free