Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Explain why it is true that for a firm in a perfectly competitive market, \(P=M R=A R\).

Short Answer

Expert verified
In a perfectly competitive market, a firm is a price taker and can sell any number of units at the market-determined price, making this price equal to the Average Revenue (AR) and the Marginal Revenue (MR). Thus, for a firm in such a market, it holds true that \(P = MR = AR\).

Step by step solution

01

Understanding Perfect Competition

In a perfectly competitive market, firms are price takers. This implies they have no control over the price determined by the market due to the existence of many sellers selling a homogeneous product. The demand curve facing each firm is perfectly elastic, implying any quantity can be sold at the market price.
02

Understanding Average Revenue (AR)

Average revenue (AR) is the revenue per unit of output sold. It is calculated by dividing total revenue (\(TR\)) by the quantity (\(Q\)). In a perfect competition, AR is equal to the firm's selling price (\(P\)), i.e., \(AR = TR/Q = P\).
03

Understanding Marginal Revenue (MR)

Marginal revenue (MR) is the additional revenue a firm receives when it sells an additional unit of output. Since the firm in a perfectly competitive market can sell any number of units at the market price, the MR is also equal to the price (\(P\)), i.e., \(MR = P\). As a result, we obtain \(P = MR = AR\).

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Price Takers
In a perfectly competitive market, individual firms operate as 'price takers.' This means that they accept the market price as given and have no influence over it. Why is this the case? Imagine a marketplace filled with numerous sellers, each offering an identical product. Since there are so many sellers and the product is exactly the same no matter from whom you buy, none of these sellers can charge more than the current market price without losing their customers to competitors.

The demand curve for a price taker is perfectly elastic. In other words, a firm can sell as much as it wants at the market price, but if it tries to increase its price even slightly, the quantity demanded for its product will drop to zero. This scenario enforces the firm's status as a price taker and ensures that the strategic individual pricing decisions are not applicable. Understanding this is crucial when dissecting the connection between price, average revenue (AR), and marginal revenue (MR) in a perfectly competitive market.
Average Revenue (AR)
Average revenue (AR) simplifies the understanding of how much a firm typically earns per unit of the product sold. It's a straightforward but essential concept in identifying the performance of a business in the context of sales and pricing strategies. Calculated by dividing the total revenue (TR) by the quantity sold (Q), it comes down to this simple equation:
\[ AR = \frac{TR}{Q} \]
In a perfect competition, where price takers reign, the AR is equal to the selling price (P). The product's uniform price across all sellers means that as long as the firm sells at the market price, the average revenue per unit remains constant, regardless of how many units are sold. Therefore, in such markets, \( AR = P \), signaling that the average revenue does not change with output – a distinctive trait of perfect competition.
Marginal Revenue (MR)
Marginal revenue (MR) is a concept that might seem puzzling at first, but it is the lifeblood of understanding firm behaviors in economics. MR represents the additional income obtained from selling one more unit. Technically, it's the derivative of the total revenue function with respect to the quantity. But in a perfectly competitive market, where each additional unit of output can be sold at the constant market price (P), the marginal revenue doesn't change with each additional unit sold. This results in a formula that is simple yet profound:
\( MR = \frac{\Delta TR}{\Delta Q} = P \)
It details that the extra revenue from an extra unit of a product will be exactly the price at which the product is sold. Since price takers in such a market face a horizontal demand curve, all the outputs are sold at this same price leading to the conclusion \( P = MR \). Connecting this back to the average revenue, for a firm in perfect competition, it follows that \( AR = MR = P \), painting a clear picture of how intimately price, AR, and MR are linked in this market structure.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that each of the following is true: (1) The laptop computer industry is perfectly competitive, and the firms that assemble laptops do not also make the displays or screens; (2) the laptop display industry is also perfectly competitive; and (3) because the demand for laptop displays is currently relatively small, firms in the laptop display industry have not been able to take advantage of all the economies of scale in laptop display production. Use a graph of the laptop computer market to illustrate the long-run effects on equilibrium price and quantity in the laptop computer market of a substantial and sustained increase in the demand for laptop computers. Use another graph to show the effect on the cost curves of a typical firm in the laptop computer industry. Briefly explain your graphs. Do your graphs indicate that the laptop computer industry is a constant-cost industry, an increasing-cost industry, or a decreasing-cost industry?

What is meant by allocative efficiency? What is meant by productive efficiency? Briefly discuss the difference between these two concepts.

What is a price taker? When are firms likely to be price takers?

(Related to Solved Problem 12.6 on page 439) Discuss the following statement: "In a perfectly competitive market, in the long run consumers benefit from reductions in costs, but firms don't." Don't firms also benefit from cost reductions because they are able to earn larger profits?

Frances sells pencils in the perfectly competitive pencil market. Her output per day and her total cost are shown in the following table: $$ \begin{array}{|c|c|} \hline \text { Output per Day } & \text { Total Cost } \\ \hline 0 & \$ 1.00 \\ \hline 1 & 2.50 \\ \hline 2 & 3.50 \\ \hline 3 & 4.20 \\ \hline 4 & 4.50 \\ \hline 5 & 5.20 \\ \hline 6 & 6.80 \\ \hline 7 & 8.70 \\ \hline 8 & 10.70 \\ \hline 9 & 13.00 \\ \hline \end{array} $$ a. If the current equilibrium price in the pencil market is \(\$ 1.80,\) how many pencils will Frances produce, what price will she charge, and how much profit (or loss) will she make? Draw a graph to illustrate your answer. Your graph should be clearly labeled and should include Frances's demand, \(A T C, A V C, M C,\) and \(M R\) curves; the price she is charging; the quantity she is producing; and the area representing her profit (or loss). b. Suppose the equilibrium price of pencils falls to \(\$ 1.00\). Now how many pencils will Frances produce, what price will she charge, and how much profit (or loss) will she make? Show your work. Draw a graph to illustrate this situation, using the instructions in part (a). c. Suppose the equilibrium price of pencils falls to \(\$ 0.25 .\) Now how many pencils will Frances produce, what price will she charge, and how much profit (or loss) will she make?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free