Warning: foreach() argument must be of type array|object, bool given in /var/www/html/web/app/themes/studypress-core-theme/template-parts/header/mobile-offcanvas.php on line 20

Butchart Gardens is a very large garden in Victoria, British Columbia, renowned for its beautiful plants. It is so large that it could hold many times more visitors than currently visit it. The garden charges an admission fee of approximately \(\$ 30 .\) At this price, 1,000 people visit the garden each day. If admission were free, 2,000 people would visit each day. a. Are visits to Butchart Gardens excludable or nonexcludable? Are they rival in consumption or nonrival? What type of good is it? b. In a diagram, illustrate the demand curve for visits to Butchart Gardens. Indicate the situation when Butchart Gardens charges an admission fee of \(\$ 30 .\) Also indicate the situation when Butchart Gardens charges no admission fee. c. Illustrate the deadweight loss from charging a \(\$ 30\) admission fee. Explain why charging a \(\$ 30\) admission fee is inefficient.

Short Answer

Expert verified
A visit to the Butchart Gardens represents a club good, as it is excludable and nonrival in consumption. The deadweight loss that arises from charging a $30 admission fee is due to the lost benefit that would have been enjoyed by those who would have visited the Gardens if the price were lower or free. This leads to a decreased total surplus and economic inefficiency, as the Gardens could have accommodated more visitors without increasing costs.

Step by step solution

01

Determine Excludability and Rivalry of Visits to Butchart Gardens

First, we need to evaluate whether visits to Butchart Gardens are excludable or nonexcludable, and whether they are rival in consumption or nonrival. Excludable goods can prevent people who don't pay for them from consuming the good. In this case, visits to Butchart Gardens can be considered excludable, as there is an admission fee and the management can prevent people who don't pay from entering the garden. Rival goods are those that, if consumed by one person, cannot be consumed by another person. Visits to Butchart Gardens are nonrival in consumption because the Gardens is very large and can hold a larger number of visitors than it currently has. Thus, one person's consumption (visit) does not significantly impact another's. Therefore, visits to Butchart Gardens are excludable and nonrival in consumption, making it a club good.
02

Illustrating the Demand Curve and Indicating Situations

Now, we will create a demand curve based on the given price and visitor data. At the price of \(\$30\), the Gardens receive 1,000 visitors. If admission were free, there would be 2,000 visitors. Let the vertical axis represent the price (P) and the horizontal axis represent the quantity of visitors (Q). 1. Plot the point (1,000, 30) on the graph, representing the situation of 1,000 visitors when the price is \(\$30\). 2. Plot the point (2,000, 0) on the graph, representing the situation of 2,000 visitors when admission is free. 3. Connect the two points to create the demand curve.
03

Illustrating Deadweight Loss and Explaining Inefficiency

Finally, we will calculate the deadweight loss of charging a \(\$30\) admission fee and explain why it is inefficient. 1. Draw a horizontal line at \(\$30\) to find the level of output where price equals marginal cost (efficient allocation). 2. Find the intersection point between the demand curve and the \(\$30\) line, and label it A. 3. Find the area of the triangle between point A, the \(\$30\) line, and the demand curve. This triangle represents the deadweight loss of charging the \(\$30\) admission fee. Charging a \(\$30\) admission fee is inefficient because it results in a deadweight loss. This means that there is a loss in total surplus (the total value to consumers minus total costs), representing the lost benefit that would have been enjoyed by those who would have visited the Gardens had the price been lower or free. With fewer visits, both the Gardens and potential visitors are not achieving the highest total overall satisfaction and economic efficiency, as the Gardens could have held many more visitors without increasing costs.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Excludability
Excludability refers to the ability to prevent people from using a good or service unless they pay for it. If you can stop someone from accessing the good because they haven't paid, then it is considered excludable.

In the case of Butchart Gardens, visits are excludable because there is an entrance fee. If someone doesn't pay the approximate $30 admission, they cannot enter the garden. This means the management has control over who accesses the garden, based on payment, which makes visits to Butchart Gardens excludable.

This is important because excludable goods often require a management system to enforce the access, which means there is typically an associated cost with providing and maintaining this exclusivity.
Rivalry in Consumption
Rivalry in consumption occurs when one person's use of a good diminishes the ability of others to use it. If a good is rival in consumption, it becomes less available or of lower quality as more people use it.

Butchart Gardens, however, is nonrival in consumption. This means that one person's visit does not prevent another's. The garden is spacious, and its capacity for visitors exceeds current visitor numbers. Therefore, an additional visitor does not hinder someone else's ability to enjoy the garden.

Understanding rivalry helps in determining how resources might be strained or maintained, and in this case, knowing the nature of rivalry ensures that the garden can welcome many visitors without diminishing the experience for anyone.
Club Goods
Club goods are a unique category of goods that are both excludable and nonrival in consumption. They are often characterized by the ability to prevent access and allow shared enjoyment without overcrowding concerns.

Visits to Butchart Gardens exemplify club goods. They are excludable due to the entry fee, ensuring only those who pay can enter. Yet, they are nonrival as the garden can accommodate more visitors without diminishing anyone's experience.

Club goods often involve some form of membership or access control, such as the garden's ticket system. This structure allows for sustainable management while ensuring maximum satisfaction for paying visitors, capitalizing on the property of nonrivalry while maintaining controlled access.
Deadweight Loss
Deadweight loss is an economic concept that refers to the loss of economic efficiency when the equilibrium for a good or service is not achieved. It occurs when the supply and demand balance is disrupted, leading to a loss in total potential welfare.

In the context of Butchart Gardens, charging a $30 admission fee creates a deadweight loss. This is because the fee prevents some potential visitors from entering, despite there being no congestion or depletion of resources. The garden receives 1,000 visitors at the $30 fee, but could accommodate 2,000 if it were free.

The area between the demand curve, the price line, and the potential free admission visits represents this deadweight loss. This indicates a missed opportunity for both the garden and visitors to maximize satisfaction and economic benefit, resulting in inefficiency as people who value the garden at less than $30 are excluded despite available capacity. This inefficiency reduces the total welfare and satisfaction the garden could potentially offer if the price were adjusted.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

An economist gives the following advice to a museum director: "You should introduce 'peak pricing.' At times when the museum has few visitors, you should admit visitors for free. And at times when the museum has many visitors, you should charge a higher admission fee." a. When the museum is quiet, is it rival or nonrival in consumption? Is it excludable or nonexcludable? What type of good is the museum at those times? What would be the efficient price to charge visitors during that time, and why? b. When the museum is busy, is it rival or nonrival in consumption? Is it excludable or nonexcludable? What type of good is the museum at those times? What would be the efficient price to charge visitors during that time, and why?

Software has historically been an artificially scarce good-it is nonrival because the cost of replication is negligible once the investment to write the code is made, but software companies make it excludable by charging for user licenses. But then open-source software emerged, most of which is free to download and can be modified and maintained by anyone. a. Discuss the free-rider problem that might exist in the development of open- source software. What effect might this have on quality? Why does this problem not exist for proprietary software, such as the products of a company like Microsoft or Adobe? b. Some argue that open-source software serves an unsatisfied market demand that proprietary software ignores. Draw a typical diagram that illustrates how proprietary software may be underproduced. Put the price and marginal cost of software on the vertical axis and the quantity of software on the horizontal axis. Draw a typical demand curve and a marginal cost curve \((M C)\) that is always equal to zero. Assume that the software company charges a positive price, \(P,\) for the software. Label the equilibrium point and the efficient point.

The government is involved in providing many goods and services. For each of the goods or services listed, determine whether it is rival or nonrival in consumption and whether it is excludable or nonexcludable. What type of good is it? Without government involvement, would the quantity provided be efficient, inefficiently low, or inefficiently high? a. Street signs b. Amtrak rail service c. Regulations limiting pollution d. A congested interstate highway without tolls e. A lighthouse on the coast

A residential community has 100 residents who are concerned about security. The accompanying table gives the total cost of hiring a 24 -hour security service as well as each individual resident's total benefit. \begin{tabular}{c|c|c} Quantity of security guards & Total cost & Total individual benefit to each resident \\ \hline 0 & \(\$ 0\) & \(\$ 0\) \\ 1 & 150 & 10 \\ 2 & 300 & 16 \\ 3 & 450 & 18 \\ 4 & 600 & 19 \end{tabular} a. Explain why the security service is a public good for the residents of the community. b. Calculate the marginal cost, the individual marginal benefit for each resident, and the marginal social benefit. c. If an individual resident were to decide about hiring and paying for security guards on his or her own, how many guards would that resident hire? d. If the residents act together, how many security guards will they hire?

Your economics professor assigns a group project for the course. Describe the free-rider problem that can lead to a suboptimal outcome for your group. To combat this problem, the instructor asks you to evaluate the contribution of your peers in a confidential report. Will this evaluation have the desired effects?

See all solutions

Recommended explanations on Economics Textbooks

View all explanations

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free